Innovation with and without patents Josef Taalbi1 1Department of Economic History Lund University

2025-05-05 0 0 1.73MB 50 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
Innovation with and without patents
Josef Taalbi,1
1Department of Economic History, Lund University
E-mail: josef.taalbi@ekh.lu.se.
A long-standing discussion is to what extent patents can be used to monitor
trends in innovation activity. This study quantifies the amount and quality
of information about actual innovation contained in the patent system, based
on 4,460 Swedish innovations (1970-2015) that have been matched to interna-
tional patents. The results show that most innovations were not patented and
that among those that were, 43.9% of all innovations, only a fraction can be
identified with patent quality data. The best-performing models identify 17%
of all information about innovations, equivalent to an information loss of at
least 83%. Econometric tests also show that the fraction of innovations re-
sponding to strengthened patent laws during the period were on average 8%
percent. The overlap between the patent and innovation systems is hence more
modest than often assumed. This accentuates the need to, alongside patents,
develop versatile approaches in order to induce and monitor various aspects
of innovation.
1
arXiv:2210.04102v1 [econ.GN] 8 Oct 2022
Introduction
Innovation is widely viewed as essential for achieving long-run economic development and
sustainability. Measuring and monitoring innovation is therefore key for our understanding of
trends in technology and structural transformation over time and between countries. Innovation
is typically measured through various indicators covering different stages of the innovation
process [1], including scientific output, R & D expenditures and patents, or compound indices
of these [2, 3, 4].
Patents remain the most widely used innovation indicator and for good reason. Patent
records are publicly and readily available, contain detailed information about inventors and
inventing firms globally and for long time periods. In addition, patent records offer ways of
assessing the value of patents through patent citation counts [5, 6, 7], and the insights into
knowledge flows that can be gained from analysis of patent citations are unparalleled [6].
There are important sources of discrepancies, however, between innovations and patents,
and the extent to which the patent and innovation systems overlap is not settled [8, 9]. The
question of how much the patent and innovation systems actually overlap also haunts policy
discussions. The patent system has come under fire for being inefficient [10, 11, 12], distort-
ing incentives or blocking innovation [13, 14], while the number of innovations affected by
patents or patent laws has been argued to be low or uncertain [15, 16, 8, 17]. Gaining a better
understanding of this overlap is therefore key also for policy debates.
This study presents evidence about the amount and quality of information on innovation that
is possible to identify within the patent system. In doing so, this study addresses methodological
issues and supplies evidence for broader discussions about the relationship between the patent
and innovation systems. This effort is based on a literature-based innovation output (LBIO)
database [18, 19] containing 4,460 commercialized innovations in Sweden, one of the world’s
2
highest ranked innovative economies [4]. These innovations, commercialized between 1970
and 2015, were linked to 13,561 patents across various national and supra-national patent of-
fices, through manual and machine-learning-assisted searches in Google Patents. The matching
methodology is detailed in the supplementary materials.
This data enables examination of the information overlap between patents and commercial-
ized innovations from multiple angles. This study views the problem of measuring innovation
as analogous to information transmission from a source to a receiver through a noisy channel
(Fig. 1). The key question is how much information the receiver (patent analyst) has about the
source (innovations). This study phrases this question as follows: what fraction of innovations
can be correctly identified by a patent analyst, based on data available within the patent system?
This fraction is circumscribed by three factors (Fig. 1). First, not all innovations are
patented, but some fraction ρthat is determined by property laws and appropriability strate-
gies. Previous research proposes varying estimates of the percentage of innovations that are
patented, from 9.6% [8], 36% [20] to almost half [21]. A second important issue is that patents,
strictly speaking, reflect invention, which may, or may not, lead to innovation, viz. new com-
binations that are commercialized or otherwise come into economic use [22]. Patenting is also
often the outcome of strategic decisions to protect intellectual advances, rather than reflecting
innovation activity [23]. Therefore, to weed out less important or less valuable patents, the usual
strategy is to use patent citations. However, while some studies suggest patent citations to be
a good measure of economic value [5, 6, 7], others find that patent citation counts are “noisy”,
heterogeneous over time, across sectors and countries [24, 25, 26, 9, 27]. Such quality-adjusted
indicators must balance two aspects: the amount of actual innovations (true positives) that are
captured, the recall α, and the fraction of true positives among all patents identified, the preci-
sion β. The information about innovations in the final patent selection is then defined by the
fraction of innovations covered and the precision of the selection: ρ×α×β. This measure is
3
further motivated in the supplementary materials.
ρpatented recall α
with precision β
Innovations Patent
data
Identification
of
patented
innova-
tions
Skype
Spotify
NMT
SBR
Skype
Spotify
Patent 1
Patent 2
Patent 3
Skype
Patent 1
Patent 2
ρ= 1/2α= 1/2,
β= 1/3
Figure 1: (a) Innovations and patents viewed as information transmission through a noisy chan-
nel. A fraction ρof Ninnovations enter into the patent system. The patent system also contains
noise in the form of non-commercialized inventions that can be reduced through patent quality
measures. The quality of the information about innovations depends on the fraction of true
positives identified (recall α), and the probability that a patent identified is truly an innovation
(precision β). (b) Example. If asked to name the patented innovation, the patent analyst would
on average be able to correctly identify 1 correctly a third of the times. The information about
the original source, as a fraction of the total, is ρ×α×βor 1/12 in the example.
Results
Patent propensity We turn first to the propensity to patent (ρin Fig. 1). The main results
are given in Fig. 2 and further detailed in Table S1. The results show that 43.9 percent of
all innovations, launched in 1970-2015, were patented in at least one patent office, whereas
4
(a)
(b)
(c) (d)
Figure 2: (a) Patent propensity by patent office. (b) Total patent propensity, by commercial-
ization year 1970-2015, (c) EPO, USPTO, Sweden, Japan, (d) Patent propensity across sectors
(ISIC Rev. 3), all patent offices. Note: Results not given when sectoral counts are below five.
patenting propensity to any one single patent office was highest for the Swedish and US patent
offices. Combining data from two or three patent offices however suffices to capture a near-
complete set of all patented innovations (Fig. 2a).
Piercing below the aggregate reveals stark differences over time and across sectors. The
patent propensity to the Swedish Patent Office has increased from a low level of 13.9% in 1970
to 57.7% in 2000, followed by a decrease back to 21.1% in 2015. The patent propensity to
USPTO increased from 26.6% in 1970 to 49.0% in 2000, followed by a decrease back to 25.3%
in 2015 (Fig. 2c). These results are in line with the emergence of a pro-patent era in the late
5
摘要:

InnovationwithandwithoutpatentsJosefTaalbi,11DepartmentofEconomicHistory,LundUniversityE-mail:josef.taalbi@ekh.lu.se.Along-standingdiscussionistowhatextentpatentscanbeusedtomonitortrendsininnovationactivity.Thisstudyquantiestheamountandqualityofinformationaboutactualinnovationcontainedinthepatent...

展开>> 收起<<
Innovation with and without patents Josef Taalbi1 1Department of Economic History Lund University.pdf

共50页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:50 页 大小:1.73MB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-05

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 50
客服
关注