A solution for external costs beyond negotiation and taxation Alexandre Magno de Melo Fariaa Hélde A. D. Hdomb aFederal University of Mato Grosso F aculty of Economics. Brazil.

2025-04-27 0 0 287.34KB 18 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
A solution for external costs beyond negotiation and taxation
Alexandre Magno de Melo Fariaa Hélde A. D. Hdomb
aFederal University of Mato Grosso, Faculty of Economics. Brazil.
bUniversity of Beira Interior, Portugal
Abstract
This article aims to launch light on the limitations of the Coase and Pigou approach in the
solution of externalities. After contextualizing the need for integration of ecological and
economic approaches, we are introducing a new conceptual proposal complementary to
conventional economic approaches. Whose process is guaranteed by a set of diffuse
agents in the economy that partially reverses entropy formation and marginal external costs
generated by also diffuse agents? The approach differs in six fundamentals from traditional
theory and proposes a new way of examining the actions of agents capable of reducing
entropy and containing part of external costs in the market economy.
Keywords: Coase-Pigou, External Cost, Negative Externality, Reverse Externality.
1. Introduction
The beginning of the 21st century has been marked by transformations that are directly or
indirectly interconnected through the various problems that society, and the economy and
technological development, and the environment are as their main drivers of these
transformations. In particular, the energy consumption by humanity to run the economy of
countries (Hdom and Fuinhas, 2020). These transformations have been increasingly
accentuated since the first meeting of nations at Rio 92 to discuss the relevance of
sustainability policies for the world to continue its development without compromising the
survival of human beings on the Planet. Since then, technological transformations through
innovation policies and energy and economic efficiency have been the subject of
increasingly appropriate investigation. Therefore, this entire relationship between economy,
human beings, ecosystems, and the environment is an increasingly important source of
analysis. In this work, we focus on interactions that the economic system is primarily
responsible for, and its direct or indirect impact entails a series of general or
macroeconomic problems. Thus, a new theoretical assessment approach is launched to fill
a gap in this relationship mediated by positive and negative externalities.
For example, the research provides a new theoretical framework to support researchers in
rotating fields such as Environmental Sciences, Environmental Economics, Ecological
Economics, Energy Economics, Natural Resource Economics, and Social Sciences, not
limited to this scientific area group, more to all those who make use of science to improve
the understanding of the impacts of human and economic actions and activities on the life
and well-being of society. That is the search for balance between environmental, social,
and economic forces, whose interactions the economic system is responsible for. The
method involves the precise analysis of the development of externalities in the economy
and the determinants of behavior change during the process of extracting resources for
manufacturing, trading, consuming, and disposing of economic goods. In this scenario, the
research facilitates the understanding of the impacts, and the results are extremely relevant
to the Energy, environmental, and economic nexus. Especially related to the addition of the
theme of renewable energies, energy security, and the strong reduction of emissions for
the Low Carbon economy. In addition, it helps to guide future empirical research in the
search for answers to problems related to externalities. In other words, this work takes a
different path from the conventional or unsustainable point of view of economics to
improve the understanding of the reverse impacts of externalities.
Unprecedented, the world is simultaneously experiencing a global health crisis along with
economic and environmental problems. There is neither consensus, and also a quick fix to
stabilize global warming at 1.5 °C as detailed in the Paris Agreement. However, the
COVID19 pandemic especially revealed that the loss of life far outweighs the economic
benefits in the humanitarian context. Whilst, in the economic context the data showed a
sharp retraction in productive activities due to the impacts of the global health crisis. At the
same time, CO2 emissions and other pollution factors also drastically decreased in the
environmental context during the isolation peak. The reality of the Global Pandemic has
forced politicians, country governments, and policymakers to rethink the sense of priority
(the lives of people, citizens, or profit and economic growth). However, the open debate
seems to lead to a well-known path, that is "degrowth" and the "energy transition" as a
reply to tackles the problem by parts. Which of these parts is the best choice will depend
largely on the benefits associated with each of the alternatives. Another problem is that if
the degrowth alternative can be a way to delay the climate crisis responding to the
generational effect, this alternative can mean, to some degree, not only the worsening of
people's living conditions. But also, the corresponding gap between poverty and wealth,
impacting the aggregate effect. Alternatively, the energy transition poses enormous
challenges, but it is more real than considering a utopian hypothesis. This is:
- How much of the world's GDP needs to decrease to have a minimum level of climate and
energy security?
- Furthermore, how much of this decrease can be distributed among rich, emerging, and
poor countries until the complete transition from fossil energy to renewable energy?
These are pressing questions that the search for answers can help the set of results
explained by modern economic models.
Our analysis proposal is based on well-known literature, i.e., we launch the proposal to
investigate these phenomena through an intrinsic relationship of positive and negative
externalities, drawing a parallel simultaneously. For example, pollution imposes a cost on
society. That is the loss of biodiversity, climate change, and other effects that bring costs to
societies. A major problem has been the depletion of natural resources, which played a
double role in the development of countries (Hdom et al., 2019). This is because the
depletion of natural resources causes a negative change in the natural environment and
because the natural resources extracted to carry out economic production generate waste
(pollution). This dual role is theorized and explained by theories such as Natural Resources
and traditionally that of externality, among others linked to the investigation of the effects of
the economy on the environment.
In this sense, we have divided the work into six parts, in addition to the introduction, the
second part sheds light on the limitations of Coase and Pigou's approach in solving
externalities. In the third part, we contextualize the need for integration of ecological and
economic approaches, and finally, in the fourth part, we present a new complementary
conceptual proposal. In the sixth part, the conclusion and limitations of the research are
provided.
2. Background
The debate about externalities is found in “Principles of Economics” by Marshall (1890)
when the author mentions a process for the formation of external economies. This
approach is well established within the welfare of the Neoclassic economy, considering the
ethos of economic agents which maximize their benefit in a market. Where the agents seek
to decide the better strategies for their well-being through the utility that can be achieved.
The individual decisions would not include positive or negative reactions to third parties,
but only selfishness capable of maximizing its benefits. For economic theory "the economic
model of consumer behavior is very simple: people choose the best products they can
afford to pay for." On the other hand, for Alfred Marshall, a decline in the average
production costs of a company may be possible obtain, when generated by economies
external to the firm, but internal to the industry. (e.g., technical innovations and information
exchanges) can generate positive external economies, and the greater the general
development of the industry, a positive impact on third parties is generated, but it is not
perceived ex-ante or ex-post to a decision.
To Marshall external economies are not generated internally in firms, but internally in the
industry. The larger is the concentration and sharing of information, the bigger are the
external gains. This phenomenon is often referred to as Marshall-Arrow-Romer externalities
(Sahdev, 2016). There is also another perception of this phenomenon, known as,
urbanization economies, which regards the decrease of operating costs derived from the
spatial concentration of multiple and diverse interdependent activities. In this process,
urbanization economies are external to a firm and the industry, instead generated in other
related activities, yet that reduce the overall costs because of systemic interaction. Such
economies are referred to as Jacob’s externalities (Jacobs 1969).
The second approach that affected deeply the externalities debate arose in Cambridge,
with Pigou (1920) In this work “The Economics of Welfare”, Pigou develops important
contributions to economic decisions to advance the welfare of a community. Among
others, one of his main concerns was based on actions to raise the income of a nation. An
alternative would be de the displacement of inefficient resources. Generally, industries are
interested, not in the social, but instead in the private liquid product of their stocks.
Regarding moving costs, self-interest will tend to generate equality in the marginal private
liquid product of resources invested in different ways. However, it will not tend to generate
equality in marginal liquid social products, except when marginal private liquid product and
marginal social liquid product are identical. When there is a divergence between these two
types of marginal liquid products, self-interest will not tend to maximize the national
product; and therefore, it is expected that certain specific acts of interference in the normal
economic processes do not diminish but increase the product (Pigou, 1920).
In this sense, in seeking explanations for external economies, Pigou defines the marginal
social liquid product and marginal private liquid product. Maximizing national dividends
could only be achieved when there was an identity between the two marginal liquids
products. In the presence of differences, Pigou believed in the existence of externalities that
would affect the economic agents' ability to achieve maximization, even in competitive
markets. The solutions for externalities could include the presence of fines, restrictive
contracts, subsidies, and taxes that the government could implement to re-balance the
marginal private product with the marginal social product (Pigou, 1920). Knight (1924)
criticized Pigou for does not agree with the concept of external economies and believed in
market forces to appropriate the underlying economic effects of fluctuations in production
costs. In this analytical framework, Knight believed in the free market to drive the economy
to a higher level. No corrective actions to externalities were necessary.
For Daly and Farley (2010) Knight discussed in his article, “Risk, uncertainty and Profit”
(1921), the case in which entrepreneurship supported the costs of failure and reaped the
fruits of success, but in the case of exploitation of ecosystems often the entrepreneur
appropriated the benefits and society bear the costs. A clear formation of negative
externalities from the action of private agents oriented to profit. The interesting article by
Ronald Coase, “The problem of social cost (1960) recovered the discussion regarding
externalities. For Coase, the problem of externalities should not have solely a marginal
approach as Pigou pointed out, but also one regarding its global effects. Even finding a
solution at the individual level to penalize agents for the negative effects generated, the
correction could not produce the best results at the aggregate level: “The real problem to
be solved is: A is allowed to damage B or B is right to harm A? The question is how to
avoid the most intense damage” (Coase, 1960).
Coase launches a new awareness solution, arguing that externalities are due to a lack of
market and well-defined property rights. In his perception, the correct functioning of the
market would ultimately lead to the final allocation of resources at the same level, even
with externalities and regardless of whether the cause assumes or not its costs. For Coase,
the Pigouvian solution of taxation, subsidies, or intervention does not necessarily raise the
well-being of society. Coase further argues that one should seek the optimal solution
because it believes that the benefits of removing the externality must be greater than the
transaction costs to promote adjustment. That is to say that, not always the best solution is
to tax the causer of the negative externality, the compensation for the loss, and disregard
the market conditions in which are the involved agents. Direct negotiation or a clear
definition of property rights could minimize transaction costs and increase the generated
social benefit. On the other hand, when externalities achieve several agents that tend to
infinity, the problem and the solution becomes complex.
Transaction costs can be prohibitive, interests and conflicts can be sharp, and agents
cannot recognize the solution instances. When the costs tend to infinity and social benefits
are more affordable than the cost of the transaction, the State becomes a key player in the
resolution, following the Pigouvian line. Therefore, in more localized or well-established
property rights disputes, the Coasean trading solution with low transaction costs can be an
alternative to the internalization of externalities. In a larger arena, with systemic externalities,
high transaction costs, and possible strategic actions, solely the performance of supra-
individual representation like the State can reduce the externalities with an acceptable
transaction cost.
3. Definitions of the microeconomics
Microeconomics textbooks reserve to externalities a section regarding market failures”. In
said section, along with information asymmetries, public goods, incomplete markets, and
摘要:

AsolutionforexternalcostsbeyondnegotiationandtaxationAlexandreMagnodeMeloFariaaHéldeA.D.HdombaFederalUniversityofMatoGrosso,FacultyofEconomics.Brazil.bUniversityofBeiraInterior,PortugalAbstractThisarticleaimstolaunchlightonthelimitationsoftheCoaseandPigouapproachinthesolutionofexternalities.Aftercon...

展开>> 收起<<
A solution for external costs beyond negotiation and taxation Alexandre Magno de Melo Fariaa Hélde A. D. Hdomb aFederal University of Mato Grosso F aculty of Economics. Brazil..pdf

共18页,预览4页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:18 页 大小:287.34KB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-04-27

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 18
客服
关注