Symmetric Nash equilibrium of political polarization in a two-party system

2025-05-02 0 0 502.8KB 14 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
Symmetric Nash equilibrium of political polarization in
a two-party system
Jonghoon Kim1
Department of Physics, Pukyong National University, Busan 48513, Korea
Hyeong-Chai Jeong
Department of Physics and Astronomy, Sejong University, Seoul 05006, Korea
Seung Ki Baek
Department of Scientific Computing, Pukyong National University, Busan 48513, Korea
Abstract
The median-voter hypothesis (MVH) predicts convergence of two party plat-
forms across a one-dimensional political spectrum during majoritarian elec-
tions. From the viewpoint of the MVH, an explanation of polarization is
that each election has a different median voter so that a party cannot please
all the median voters at the same time. We consider two parties competing
to win voters along a one-dimensional spectrum and assume that each party
nominates one candidate out of two in the primary election, for which the
electorates represent only one side of the whole population. We argue that
all the four candidates will come to the same distance from the median of
the total population through best-response dynamics.
Keywords: Political polarization, Median-voter hypothesis, Best-response
dynamics
Email address: seungki@pknu.ac.kr (Seung Ki Baek)
1Current address: Department of Energy Engineering, Korea Institute of Energy Tech-
nology, Naju 58330, Korea
Preprint submitted to Elsevier October 5, 2022
arXiv:2210.01336v1 [physics.soc-ph] 4 Oct 2022
1. Introduction
Statistical physics deals with macroscopic patterns emerging from micro-
scopic interactions. Collective decision-making is an example of such emer-
gent phenomena arising from individual-level interactions [1, 2, 3, 4]. Broadly
speaking, the group of activities associated with collective decision-making
in society can be referred to as politics, and it is why statistical physicists
have viewed the interplay between individual choices and political changes
within the framework of complex systems [5, 6, 7, 8]. One of widely accepted
political values is democracy, according to which the people have the right
to rule. A democratic government thus has an excellent incentive to meet
the people’s demands, but the price is political instability: the governmen-
tal policies may suddenly change if the power is transferred to the opposing
party by election, and the change can be especially drastic when political
opinions are polarized to a great degree.
Whether political polarization is an inevitable part of democracy is not
clear. As will be explained below, in a two-party system, the median-voter
hypothesis (MVH) predicts that the two parties along a one-dimensional po-
litical spectrum will converge to the median voter’s position through majori-
tarian elections [9]. The assumptions of the MVH might look too restrictive,
but it has been reported in congressional voting that very often the issue re-
duces to a one-dimensional matter [10]. In such a one-dimensional political
landscape, a two-party system is robust, as assumed by the MVH, because
a centrist party cannot easily find a political “niche” between two existing
parties [11]. Thus, the question still remains: Why are they so polarized?
It may be attributed to social homophily or echo chambers [12, 13], and
temporary polarization may be consistent with Bayesian updating [14]. Many
of the existing approaches assume that people update their political positions
through mechanistic interaction with neighbors such as homophily, assimila-
tion, and differentiation [15, 16, 17, 18]. A recent study answers this question
by pointing out that voters are not as rational as assumed in the MVH [19]:
According to this idea, voters will rather satisfice than maximize their util-
ity functions. By adapting to such voting behavior with a simple gradient
ascent method, the parties can develop symmetric polarization, maintaining
an equal distance from the median voter.
In this work, we wish to examine an alternative explanation [20], which ar-
gues that the median voter’s position experienced by a party may be different
from election to election: For example, a party has to nominate a candidate
2
before a presidential election. To become the nominee, candidates in the
primary should take opinions from their own supporters seriously, even if the
supporters’ overall position differs from the general public opinion, because
their votes are needed to win the primary. By considering the nomination
process as a part of election, this approach explains permanent polarization
without resorting to cognitive biases and bounded rationality. In addition,
our work provides a testable prediction that polarization will only increase
further if the payoff for the loser of the final election also becomes valuable
enough, which has not been proposed by other models.
In the next section, we will formulate our model as a game of two-round
competition among four players, whose strategies are their political positions.
The Nash equilibria will be identified. We then propose how to update the
players’ positions to reach one of the Nash equilibria. Such dynamic con-
sideration is important in several aspects: First, the existence of plausible
dynamics ensures the feasibility of the discovered equilibrium. Second, the
time scale to reach the equilibrium can be estimated: If it diverges, devi-
ation from the equilibrium can prove more pervasive than predicted by a
static analysis [21, 22]. Third, when multiple equilibria exist, the distribu-
tion of convergence points will generally require dynamical consideration. As
a model of dynamics, one could consider an evolutionary process which works
in a large population of simple-minded agents, but we believe that a variety
of strategic moves in the course of election can be better described by best-
response dynamics among the candidates, according to which each candidate
deliberately seeks a position to be the final winner given that the other com-
petitors’ positions are held fixed. The whole dynamics is thus projected onto
four candidates, and the electorate react to the candidates instantaneously
with fixed political positions, which is an assumption that we have borrowed
from the MVH. The key point is that everyone in our model society seeks
the best response to the given configuration, and this is one of common ap-
proaches to model human behavior in evolutionary game theory [23]. In
other words, each player tries to maximize his or her own objective function,
as is not uncommon in physics, but an important difference of game theory
from physics is that such individual optimization may drive the total system
away from an optimal point.
3
摘要:

SymmetricNashequilibriumofpoliticalpolarizationinatwo-partysystemJonghoonKim1DepartmentofPhysics,PukyongNationalUniversity,Busan48513,KoreaHyeong-ChaiJeongDepartmentofPhysicsandAstronomy,SejongUniversity,Seoul05006,KoreaSeungKiBaekDepartmentofScienti cComputing,PukyongNationalUniversity,Busan48513,K...

展开>> 收起<<
Symmetric Nash equilibrium of political polarization in a two-party system.pdf

共14页,预览3页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:14 页 大小:502.8KB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-02

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 14
客服
关注