Synchronization in a Kuramoto Mean Field Game Rene CarmonaQuentin CormierH. Mete Soner October 25 2022

2025-05-02 0 0 700.06KB 29 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
Synchronization in a Kuramoto Mean Field Game
Rene CarmonaQuentin CormierH. Mete Soner
October 25, 2022
Abstract
The classical Kuramoto model is studied in the setting of an infinite horizon mean field
game. The system is shown to exhibit both synchronization and phase transition. Incoherence
below a critical value of the interaction parameter is demonstrated by the stability of the
uniform distribution. Above this value, the game bifurcates and develops self-organizing time
homogeneous Nash equilibria. As interactions become stronger, these stationary solutions
become fully synchronized. Results are proved by an amalgam of techniques from nonlinear
partial differential equations, viscosity solutions, stochastic optimal control and stochastic
processes.
Key words: Mean field games, Kuramoto model, Synchronization, viscosity solutions.
Mathematics Subject Classification: 35Q89, 35D40, 39N80, 91A16, 92B25
1 Introduction
Originally motivated by systems of chemical and biological oscillators, the classical Kuramoto
model [
17
] has found an amazing range of applications from neuroscience to Josephson
junctions in superconductors, and has become a key mathematical model to describe self
organization in complex systems. These autonomous oscillators are coupled through a
nonlinear interaction term which plays a central role in the long time behavior of the system.
While the system is unsynchronized when this term is not sufficiently strong, fascinatingly
they exhibit an abrupt transition to self organization above a critical value of the interaction
parameter. Synchronization is an emergent property that occurs in a broad range of complex
systems such as neural signals, heart beats, fire-fly lights and circadian rhythms. Expository
papers [
1
,
21
] and the references therein provide an excellent introduction to the model and
its applications.
The analysis of the coupled Kuramoto oscillators through a mean field game formalism is
first explored by [
22
,
23
] proving bifurcation from incoherence to coordination by a formal
linearization and a spectral argument. [
6
] further develops this analysis in their application
Department of Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, 08540,
USA, email:
rcarmona@princeton.edu
. Research of Carmona was partially supported by AFOSR FA9550-19-1-0291
and ARPA-E DE-AR0001289.
Inria Saclay, France, email: quentin.cormier@inria.fr.
Department of Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, 08540,
USA, email:
soner@princeton.edu
. Research of Soner was partially supported by the National Science Foundation
grant DMS 2106462.
1
arXiv:2210.12912v1 [math.OC] 24 Oct 2022
Carmona, Cormier & Soner Kuramoto Mean Field Game
to a jet-lag recovery model. We follow these pioneering studies and analyze the Kuramoto
model as a discounted infinite horizon stochastic game in the limit when the number of
oscillators goes to infinity. We treat the system of oscillators as an infinite particle system, but
instead of positing the dynamics of the particles, we let the individual particles endogenously
determine their behaviors by minimizing a cost functional and hopefully, settling in a Nash
equilibrium. Once the search for equilibrium is recast in this way, equilibria are given by
solutions of nonlinear systems. Analytically, they are characterized by a backward dynamic
programming equation coupled to a forward Fokker-Planck-Kolmogorov equation, and in
the probabilistic approach, by forward-backward stochastic differential equations. Stability
analysis of the solutions is delicate because of this forward-backward nature of the solution,
and to the best of our knowledge, it remains a challenging problem. Except possibly in the
finite horizon potential case (cf. [
3
] and the references therein) it has not been fully addressed
in the existing literature on the subject. For the stability results of the Kuramoto model in
the classical setting, the interested reader could consult [14, 15] and the references therein.
With finitely many oscillators, we consider the following version of the model already
introduced in [
6
,
23
]. We fix a large integer
N
and for
i∈ {
1
,...,N}
let
θi
t
be the phase
of the
i
-th oscillator at time
t
0. We assume the phases
θi
t
are controlled Ito diffusion
processes satisfying, d
θi
t
=
αi
t
d
t
+
σ
d
Bi
t
, where
Bi
’s are independent Brownian motions, and
the control processes
αi
are exerted by the individual oscillators so as to simultaneously
minimize their costs given by
αi7→ Ji(α) := EZ
0
eβt κ L(θi
t,θt) + 1
2(αi
t)2dt,
where
α
= (
α1,...,αN
)and
θt
= (
θ1
t,...,θN
t
). The positive constants
σ, β
are respectively,
the common standard deviations of the random shocks affecting the dynamics of the phases,
and the common discounting factor used to compute the present value of the cost. The
centrally important positive constant
κ
models the strength of the interactions between the
oscillators.
In line with the classical literature on Kuramoto’s synchronization theory, we assume
that the running cost function Lis given by
L(θi,θ) = 1
NX
j6=i
2sin (θiθj)/22=1
N
N
X
j=1
2sin (θiθj)/22.
The cost
L
accounts for the cooperation between the
N
oscillators by incentivizing them to
align their frequencies, while the term (
αi
t
)
2
represents a form of kinetic energy which is also
to be minimized. It is convenient to express the above cost functional by using the empirical
distribution measure of the oscillators as follows,
L(θi
t,θt) = c(θi
t,¯µN
t),where c(θ, µ) := Z2sin (θθ0)/22µ(dθ0),(1.1)
and the empirical measure ¯µN
tis given by,
¯µN
t= ¯µ(θt) := 1
N
N
X
j=1
δθj
t
.
As the finite particle system is essentially intractable, especially for large values of
N
, we
follow approach of [
4
,
5
,
16
,
18
,
19
,
20
] that is now considered standard, and approximate the
Nash equilibria for the above system of oscillators by letting their number
N
go to infinity.
2
Carmona, Cormier & Soner Kuramoto Mean Field Game
Then, for a given flow of probability measures
µ
= (
µt
)
t0
, the stochastic optimal control
problem for the representative oscillator is to minimize
α∈ A 7→ EZ
0
eβt `(t, Xt) + 1
2α2
tdt, (1.2)
where
A
is the set of all right-continuous and progressively measurable processes, the running
cost
`
(
t, x
)is equal to
κc
(
x, µt
)with
c
as in
(1.1)
, and
Xt
is the controlled phase of the
representative oscillator given by
Xt
=
X0
+
Rt
0αudu
+
σBt
, for a Brownian motion
Bt
. The
Nash equilibrium, as defined in Definition 3.1 below, is achieved when the flow µ= (µt)t0
is given by the marginal laws of the optimal process
X
t
. By direct methods, Lemma 4.5
proves the existence of such equilibrium flows starting from any initial distribution.
It is immediate that the uniform distribution
U
(d
x
) = d
x/
(2
π
)on the torus gives a
stationary equilibrium flow. Indeed,
c
(
x, U
)
1and therefore, the optimal control for
the above problem with the constant flow
U
is identically equal to zero. As the uniform
distribution has no special structure, it represents incoherence among the oscillators, and
when the interaction parameter is small, we show that all the solutions of the Kuramoto mean
field game converge to this incoherent state. This global attraction is proved in Lemma 4.3
for κ < βσ2/4. Theorem 4.4 considers all κless than the critical value
κc:= βσ2+σ4/2,(1.3)
and proves that there are that start “close” to the uniform distribution converge to it as
time tends to infinity. Thus, Lemma 4.3 and Theorem 4.4 reveal that incoherence is the
main paradigm in the sub-critical regime
κ < κc
. Theorem 4.1 analyzes the case
κ > κc
, and
proves that there are infinitely many self-organizing stationary solutions for these interaction
parameter values. In particular, these solutions do not converge to the incoherent uniform
distribution and numerically they are stable. Hence,
κc
is a sharp threshold for the stability
of incoherence, and there is a phase transition from total disorder to self organization exactly
at this critical interaction parameter
κc
. Furthermore, Theorem 4.2 shows convergence to
full synchronization as κgets larger.
The classical Kuramoto model with noise has been the object of many studies, and the
mean field version is the following McKean-Vlasov stochastic differential equation
dXt=κZT
sin(Xty)L(Xt)(dy) dt+σdBt,
where
L
(
Xt
)is the law of the random variable
Xt
. The uniform distribution is shown in [
12
]
to be both locally and globally stable when
κ < σ2
. The corresponding finite particle system
is studied in [
2
,
8
]. There, it is proven that the solutions of the finite model remain close to
the solution of the above equation for a very long time, on the order of
o
(
exp
(
N
)). Similar
results are also proved for the Kuramoto mean field game with an ergodic cost in [
23
], by
using bifurcation theory techniques including the Lyapunov-Schmidt reduction method to
show the existence of non-uniform stationary solutions near the critical value
κ
c
=
σ4/
2.
Rabinowitz bifurcation theorem and other global techniques are used in [
7
] for similar results.
The classical Kuramoto model and its mean field game versions provide a mechanism for
the analysis of self organization. However, they cannot model synchronization with external
drivers, thus requiring additional terms. Indeed, the jet-lag recovery model of [
6
] introduce a
cost for misalignment with the exogenously given sunlight frequency, providing an incentive
to be in synch with the environment as well. These studies are clear evidences of the modeling
potential of the mean field game formalism in all models when self organization is the salient
feature.
3
Carmona, Cormier & Soner Kuramoto Mean Field Game
The paper is organized as follows. After a short section on notation, the Kuramoto mean
field game is introduced in Section 3, and the main results are stated in Section 4. Section 5
briefly summarizes all control problems used in the paper. Stationary solutions are defined
and a fixed-point characterization is proved in Section 6. The super-critical case is studied in
Section 7 and full synchronization in Section 8. Incoherence is demonstrated in Section 9
by proving the convergence of all solutions to the uniform distribution when the interaction
parameter is small, and local stability of the uniform distribution is established in Section 10
for all
κ<κc
. For completeness, solutions starting from any distribution are constructed in
the Appendix A, and we provide the expected comparison result for a degenerate Eikonal
equation in the Appendix B.
2 Notation
The state-space is the one-dimensional torus
T
:=
R/
(2
πZ
),
P
(
T
)is the space of all probability
measures on
T
. For
ν∈ P
(
T
),
fC
(
T
), we use the standard notation
ν
(
f
) :=
RTf
(
x
)
ν
(
dx
)
.
We say that a probability measure
ν∈ P
(
T
)is the law
L
(
X
)of
X
, if
E
[
f
(
X
)] =
ν
(
f
)for
every fC(T). We also use the following space of continuous functions,
C:= {ξ= (γ, η) : [0,)7→ R2:continuous and bounded }.
We fix a filtered probability space (Ω
,F,P
)supporting an
F
-adapted Brownian motion
(
Bt
)
t0
. We assume that the filtration
F
=
{Ft}t0
satisfies the usual conditions, i.e.
F0
is complete and
Ft
is right-continuous. The initial filtration is non-trivial so that for any
probability measure
µ0∈ P
(
T
), one can construct an
F0
measurable,
T
valued random
variable
X0
with distribution
µ0
. For
t
0, the set
At
of all progressively measurable
processes α: [t, )Ris called the admissible controls, and we set A:= A0.
For µ∈ P(T), z Tand a Borel subset BT, we define the translation of µby,
µ(B;x) := µ({zT:x+zB}).(2.1)
Finally, we record several elementary trigonometric identities that are used repeatedly.
For µ∈ P(T), let c(x, µ)be as in the Introduction. As 2 (sin (x/2))2= 1 cos(x),
c(x, µ) = ZT
2 (sin ((xy)/2))2µ(dy) = 1 a(µ) cos(x)b(µ) sin(x),(2.2)
where a(µ) := µ(cos), and b(µ) := µ(sin). In particular, there is zTsuch that
a(µ(·;z)) = g(µ) := p(a(µ))2+ (b(µ))2,and b(µ(·;z)) = 0.(2.3)
3 Kuramoto mean-field game
Given a flow of probability measures µ= (µt)t0, set
`µ(t, x) := κ[c(x, µt)1] = κµt(cos) cos(x)κµt(sin) sin(x), x T, t 0.
Consider the optimal control problem (1.2) with this running cost. Then, the problem is
vµ:= inf
α∈A Jµ(α) := inf
α∈A
EZ
0
eβt `µ(t, Xα
t) + 1
2α2
tdt, (3.1)
where as in the Introduction,
Xα
t
:=
X0
+
Rt
0αudu
+
σBt
, with a Brownian motion (
Bt
)
t0
and an initial condition X0satisfying L(X0) = µ0.
4
Carmona, Cormier & Soner Kuramoto Mean Field Game
Definition 3.1.
We say that
µ
= (
µt
)
t0
is a solution to the Kuramoto mean-field game
with interaction parameter
κ
starting from initial distribution
µ0
,if there exists
α∈ A
such
that Jµ(α) = infα∈A Jµ(α)and µt=L(Xα
t)for all t0.
Example 3.2.
Consider an initial condition
X0
satisfying
Ecos
(
X0
) =
Esin
(
X0
) = 0, and
the flow of probability measures
µ
= (
µt
)
t0
with
µt
:=
L
(
X0
+
σBt
)
.
Then, for every
t
0,
`µ(t, x) = κ(µt(cos) cos(x) + µt(sin) sin(x))
=κ( cos(x)E[cos(X0+σBt)] + sin(x)E[sin(X0+σBt)])
=κ(cos(x)eσ2
2tE[cos(X0)] sin(x)eσ2
2tE[sin(X0)]) = 0.
Therefore, for any
α∈ A
,
Jµ
(
α
) =
ER
0eβt α2
t
2
d
t
0 =
Jµ
(0), implying that
α
0
is the minimizer of
Jµ
(
α
), and
µ
is the law of the dynamics controlled by
α
. Hence,
µ
is a
solution of the Kuramoto mean-field game for every κ.
Now suppose that
L
(
X0
)is the uniform probability measure on the torus
U
(d
x
) = d
x/
(2
π
).
As any translation of
U
is equal to itself,
µt
=
L
(
X0
+
σBt
) =
U
for all
t
0. Thus,
U
is a
stationary solution.
The uniform distribution represents complete incoherence, and we refer to it as the
incoherent (or uniform) solution. We next introduce the stationary solutions of the Kuramoto
mean-field games.
Definition 3.3.
We call a probability measure
µ∈ P
(
T
)a stationary solution if the constant
flow
µ
= (
µt
)
t0
with
µt
=
µ
for all
t
0is a solution of the Kuramoto mean-field game.
We say that
µ
is self-organizing or non-uniform if it is not equal to the uniform measure
U
.
We record the following simple result for future reference.
Lemma 3.4.
The uniform probability measure
U
on the torus is the incoherent stationary
solution of the Kuramoto mean-field game. Moreover, a stationary solution
µ
is the uniform
probability measure if and only if µ(cos) = µ(sin) = 0.
Proof.
In Example 3.2, we have shown that
U
is a stationary solution and that
c
(
·, U
)
1.
Now suppose that
µ
is a stationary solution with
µ
(
cos
) =
µ
(
sin
) = 0. Then, as in Example 3.2,
we conclude that the optimal solution of the control problem
(1.2)
is
α
0, and the optimal
state process satisfies d
X
t
=
σ
d
Bt
. As by stationarity
L
(
X
t
) =
µ
for every
t
0, the
density
f
of
µ
solves the Fokker-Plank equation
fxx
(
x
)=0on the torus. Hence,
f
is equal
to a constant, and µ=U.
Remark 3.5
(Invariance by translation)
.
Assume that
µ
is a stationary solution. The
symmetry of the problem implies that the translated measure
µ
(
·
;
z
)is also a stationary
solution for every z.
4 Main Results
In this section, we state all the main results of the paper. Recall the critical interaction
parameter
κc
of
(1.3)
. In Section 7, we study the super-critical case
κ > κc
, and prove the
following result.
Theorem 4.1
(Super-critical interaction: synchronization)
.
For all interaction parameters
κ > κc, there are non-uniform stationary solutions of the Kuramoto mean field game.
5
摘要:

SynchronizationinaKuramotoMeanFieldGameReneCarmona*QuentinCormier„H.MeteSoner…October25,2022AbstractTheclassicalKuramotomodelisstudiedinthesettingofaninnitehorizonmeaneldgame.Thesystemisshowntoexhibitbothsynchronizationandphasetransition.Incoherencebelowacriticalvalueoftheinteractionparameterisdem...

展开>> 收起<<
Synchronization in a Kuramoto Mean Field Game Rene CarmonaQuentin CormierH. Mete Soner October 25 2022.pdf

共29页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:29 页 大小:700.06KB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-02

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 29
客服
关注