Never Say Never Optimal Exclusion and Reserve Prices with Expectations-Based Loss-Averse Buyers Benjamin BalzerAntonio Rosato

2025-05-02 0 0 544.19KB 30 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
Never Say Never: Optimal Exclusion and Reserve Prices
with Expectations-Based Loss-Averse Buyers
Benjamin BalzerAntonio Rosato
June 16, 2023
Abstract
We study reserve prices in auctions with independent private values when bidders are expectations-
based loss averse. We find that the optimal public reserve price excludes fewer bidder types
than under risk neutrality. Moreover, we show that public reserve prices are not optimal as
the seller can earn a higher revenue with mechanisms that better leverage the “attachment
effect”. We discuss two such mechanisms: i) an auction with a secrete and random reserve
price, and ii) a two-stage mechanism where an auction with a public reserve price is followed
by a negotiation if the reserve price is not met. Both of these mechanisms expose more
bidders to the attachment effect, thereby increasing bids and ultimately revenue.
JEL classification: D44, D81, D82.
Keywords: Reference-Dependent Preferences; Loss Aversion; Reserve Price; First-Price
Auction; Second-Price Auction; Personal Equilibrium.
For helpful comments, we thank Zachary Breig, Jeff Ely, Leslie Marx and audiences at the 2021 Australasian
Economic Theory Workshop at the University of Sydney, UTS, the 2021 INFORMS Annual Meeting in Anaheim,
the 12th Conference on Economic Design in Padova, the 2022 Asia-Pacific Industrial Organization Conference in
Sydney, and the 2023 Workshop on Preferences and Bounded Rationality at the BSE Summer Forum. We are also
grateful to Andrew Barr, Gladys Berejiklian and, especially, Scott Morrison for the extended lockdowns that vastly
improved our productivity. Rosato gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Australian Research Council
(ARC) through the ARC Discovery Early Career Researcher Award DE180100190.
UTS Business School, University of Technology Sydney (Benjamin.Balzer@uts.edu.au).
University of Queensland, Universit`a di Napoli Federico II and CSEF (a.rosato@uq.edu.au).
arXiv:2210.10938v2 [econ.TH] 14 Jun 2023
1 Introduction
Reserve prices are a prevalent tool auctioneers use to raise their expected revenue. A reserve
price acts as an additional bid placed by the auctioneer since, in order to win, a buyer must also
outbid the reserve. Thus, a reserve price increases the competitiveness of an auction. Yet, this
comes at a cost for the auctioneer because trade does not happen if no buyer bids at least the
reserve price. Indeed, a reserve price excludes buyers with relatively low valuations from the auction
and reduces the overall probability of trade. Seminal theoretical contributions by Myerson (1981)
and Riley and Samuelson (1981) have characterized the revenue-maximizing reserve price as the
solution to this trade-off between decreasing the probability of trade and amplifying competitive
pressure. In particular, they show that with risk-neutral bidders having independent private values,
the optimal reserve price coincides with the classical monopoly price; hence, it is (i) deterministic
and public, (ii) always higher than the seller’s own value, and (iii) under mild conditions on the
distribution of bidders’ values, independent of the number of bidders.
However, these features are not always empirically observed. For instance, in real-world auc-
tions sellers often use secret reserve prices. A prime example is that of real-estate auctions in the
Australian state of Queensland, where prospective buyers are allowed to know whether the seller
set a reserve price, but not its exact value.1Moreover, some studies show that empirical reserve
prices are often significantly lower than what the classical models predict; see Paarsch (1997) and
Haile and Tamer (2003). There is also evidence of reserve prices that vary with the number of
bidders and auctions with no reserve price at all; see Davis et al. (2011) and Gon¸calves (2013).
Overall, this evidence suggests that sellers may face additional trade-offs not captured by the
classical risk-neutral and/or risk-averse model.2
In this paper, we analyze reserve prices in first-price auctions (FPA) and second-price auctions
(SPA) where symmetric bidders have independent private values (IPV) and are expectations-
based loss averse ´a la K˝oszegi and Rabin (2006, 2007, 2009). We derive the revenue-maximizing
reserve price for each format and highlight how loss aversion modifies the seller’s trade-off between
increasing competitive pressure and reducing the probability of trade. In particular, we show that
loss aversion can rationalize reserve prices that (i) are secret, (ii) vary with the number of bidders,
and (iii) are lower than what the theory predicts for risk-neutral and risk-averse bidders.
Section 2 introduces the auction environment and bidders’ preferences, and describes the solu-
tion concept. Following K˝oszegi and Rabin (2006), we posit that, in addition to classical material
utility, a bidder also experiences “gain-loss utility” when comparing her material outcomes to a
reference point equal to her expectations regarding those same outcomes, with losses being more
1Secret reserve prices are also documented by Elyakime et al. (1994) and Li and Perrigne (2003) in timber
auctions, and by Bajari and Horta¸csu (2004) and Hasker and Sickles (2010) in internet auctions.
2With private values, Hu et al. (2010) show that risk aversion can explain low reserve prices in the FPA but not
in the SPA; if in addition bidders have interdependent values, Hu et al. (2019) show that risk aversion can explain
low reserve prices also in the SPA.
1
painful than equal-size gains are pleasant.
We apply the solution concept of “unacclimating personal equilibrium” (UPE) introduced by
oszegi and Rabin (2007). According to this concept, bidders choose the strategy that maximizes
their payoff keeping expectations fixed, and the distribution of outcomes so generated must coincide
with the expectations; hence, when deviating from her equilibrium bid, a bidder holds her reference
point fixed.3As there might be multiple UPEs, we assume bidders select their preferred personal
equilibrium (PPE) — the one that maximizes their utility from an ex-ante perspective.
We begin our analysis in Section 3 by deriving the revenue-maximizing public reserve price
in the FPA.4First, we show that the “attachment effect” (K˝oszegi and Rabin, 2006) is the main
driving force behind the bidding behavior of loss-averse buyers. In particular, the higher the
probability with which a bidder, in equilibrium, expects to win the auction, the bigger the loss
she endures if she ends up losing it. Hence, a bidder has an incentive to increase her bid, so
as to win more often and avoid experiencing the loss. Thus, the attachment effect induces an
upward pressure on the equilibrium bidding strategy, ensuring that a bidder’s cost from an upward
deviation is higher than the benefit. Importantly, the attachment effect only affects the incentives
of a bidder who expects to win the auction with strictly positive probability — however small —
and is thus exposed to potential losses in equilibrium; yet, it does not affect those bidders who
abstain from the auction since they do not incur a loss when not winning it.
The fact that bidders who do not expect to win are not exposed to the attachment effect
has several implications for the characterization of the revenue-maximizing public reserve price.
First, it puts downward pressure on the optimal reserve price. Indeed, by increasing the reserve
price, the seller excludes a larger set of bidder types from the auction. As a bidder’s attachment
increases in her type, the higher the marginally excluded type, the larger the attachment effect
that the seller forgoes. Thus, with expectations-based loss aversion, increasing the reserve price
is more costly for the seller compared to a situation where the attachment effect is not present;
e.g., with risk-neutral bidders. This finding is especially relevant for those empirical studies that
first estimate the distribution of bidders’ values and then use the theoretical insights of Myerson
(1981) and Riley and Samuelson (1981) to estimate the revenue-maximizing reserve price as the
minimum bid that excludes all bidders with a “virtual value” lower than the seller’s value. For
instance, Paarsch (1997) and Haile and Tamer (2003) find that sellers exclude fewer types than
their estimation predicts as revenue maximizing. Yet, as our first result implies, it is theoretically
optimal to include in the auction bidders with virtual values lower than the seller’s own value
because of the attachment effect. While risk aversion can rationalize such low reserve prices in the
FPA (see Hu et al., 2010), it cannot explain it for the SPA.5
3For other applications of UPE see, for instance, Heidhues and K˝oszegi (2008, 2014) Karle and Peitz (2014,
2017), Karle and M¨oller (2020), Karle and Schumacher (2017) and Rosato (2016).
4As shown by Balzer and Rosato (2021), under UPE the FPA and SPA are revenue equivalent; therefore, our
results on the reserve price for the FPA carry over to the SPA.
5However, beyond risk aversion, several different explanations for low reserve prices in both the SPA and FPA
2
Furthermore, the optimal public reserve price varies with the number of bidders. Indeed, the
more bidders are present, the less optimistic each of them is about her chances of winning, which
reduces their attachment. Yet, this does not imply that the reserve price always increases in the
number of bidders. Indeed, when raising the reserve price, the seller forgoes the attachment effect
of the marginal type. However, with already many bidders participating, adding an extra one
reduces this cost, leading to more exclusion.6With risk aversion, instead, the optimal reserve
price (in the FPA) is decreasing in the number of bidders; see Vasserman and Watt (2021).
The fact that the attachment effect does not operate on those bidders excluded by a public
reserve price suggests that a seller could raise an even higher revenue by exposing more bidders
to this effect. In Section 4 we show that this intuition is correct. In particular, we characterize
two tactics whereby a seller can expose almost all bidders to the attachment effect, resulting in a
strictly larger revenue than an auction with a public reserve price.
In Subsection 4.1 we show that secret and random reserve prices are revenue superior to public
and deterministic ones. To see why, notice that with a secret reserve price each bidder type expects
to win the auction with strictly positive — albeit potentially arbitrarily small — probability. In
such an auction, therefore, every bidder is exposed to potential losses and thus has an incentive
to bid more aggressively in order to avoid them. Hence, by transforming the public reserve price
into a secret one, the seller can ensure that every bidder experiences the attachment effect, which
enhances revenue. By doing so, however, the seller also reduces the competitive pressure on the
buyers’ side, which could potentially harm revenue since those low-type bidders excluded under a
public reserve would be participating now. Yet, the seller can choose a distribution for the (secret)
reserve price that puts large probability mass on relatively high prices and arbitrarily small mass on
low ones. Such a distribution ensures that, while the seller exposes every bidder to the attachment
effect, the competitive pressure is almost the same as under a public reserve price.
Thus, expectations-based loss aversion provides a novel rationale for secret and random reserve
prices.7This result is reminiscent of those in Heidhues and K˝oszegi (2014) and Hancart (2022),
who characterize the optimal pricing strategy for a monopolist selling to an expectations-based
loss-averse buyer. In line with the findings of Azevedo and Gottlieb (2012), who showed that risk-
neutral sellers benefit from offering gambles to consumers exhibiting prospect-theory preferences,
these papers find that the monopolist benefits from using random prices. In particular, Heidhues
and K˝oszegi (2014) show that if the seller has sufficient commitment power, a stochastic pricing
have been proposed. These include correlated types (Levin and Smith, 1996), interdependent values (Quint, 2017;
Hu et al., 2019), endogenous entry (McAfee, 1993; Levin and Smith, 1994; Peters and Severinov, 1997), bidders’
selection neglect when sellers are privately informed about the quality of the objects they sell (Jehiel and Lamy,
2015), level-k bidders (Crawford et al., 2009) and taste projection (Gagnon-Bartsch et al., 2021).
6Menicucci (2021) obtains a similar result in the classical IPV risk-neutral model when the bidders’ virtual values
are not monotone; in contrast, our result holds also for the regular case of increasing virtual values.
7An indirect way of implementing a secret and random reserve price is via “shill bidding”, a prominent albeit
often illegal practice in real-world auctions whereby a dummy buyer submits pre-specified bids on behalf of the
seller; see Ashenfelter (1989).
3
scheme featuring low, variable sale prices and a high, sticky regular price yields more revenue than
posting a single price. Our secret and random reserve price scheme has similar features, but differs
from their characterization since we consider an environment with multiple, privately-informed
buyers. Nonetheless, we are able to draw a connection between the optimal reserve price and the
optimal monopoly pricing scheme with expectations-based loss-averse buyers that is analogous to
the well-known one for risk-neutral buyers.
In Subsection 4.2 we show that the seller can achieve a higher revenue than what is achievable
with a public reserve price by employing a simple two-stage mechanism. In this mechanism, the
seller first runs an auction with a public reserve price; then, if the reserve price is not met, with
some probability, the seller posts a price that would be accepted by those bidders whose types are
below the marginally excluded one. In this way, the seller exposes also the bidder type marginally
excluded from the initial auction to the attachment effect; this, in turn, pushes the marginal type
to bid more aggressively, thereby increasing the overall revenue.
Section 5 concludes the paper by summarizing the results of our model and discussing some
further implications. All proofs are relegated to Appendix A.
2 The Model
In this section, we introduce the auction environment and bidders’ preferences, and provide a
formal definition of our solution concept (UPE) in the context of sealed-bid auctions.
2.1 Environment
A seller auctions off an item to N2 bidders via a sealed-bid auction. Each bidder i
{1,2, ..., N}has a private value tiindependently drawn from the support t, t, with t > t = 0,
according to the same cumulative distribution function F.8We assume that Fis continuously
differentiable, with strictly positive density fon its support. Further, we impose the standard
assumption that Fhas a monotone hazard rate; i.e, f(x)
1F(x)is increasing for all xt, t. This, in
turn, implies that bidders’ “virtual values” are increasing; i.e., V(ti)ti1F(ti)
f(ti)is increasing in
ti. The seller has a commonly-known value tS[0,¯
t).
We consider two canonical selling mechanisms: the first-price sealed-bid auction (FPA) and the
second-price sealed-bid auction (SPA). We restrict attention to symmetric equilibria in increasing
strategies; in such equilibria, the bidder with the highest type wins the auction, conditional on
placing a bid above the reserve price.9Let F1denote the cumulative distribution function of the
highest order statistic among N1 draws, and denote by f1its corresponding density. Finally,
8We normalize t= 0 to simplify the exposition. Moreover, under this assumption, a seller facing risk-neutral
bidders would always choose a non-trivial reserve price; i.e., there are no corner solutions.
9Throughout the paper, we restrict attention to symmetric (i.e., non discriminatory) auction mechanisms; for a
recent analysis of asymmetric auctions with expectations-based loss-averse bidders, see Muramoto and Sogo (2022).
4
摘要:

NeverSayNever:OptimalExclusionandReservePriceswithExpectations-BasedLoss-AverseBuyers∗BenjaminBalzer†AntonioRosato‡June16,2023AbstractWestudyreservepricesinauctionswithindependentprivatevalueswhenbiddersareexpectations-basedlossaverse.Wefindthattheoptimalpublicreservepriceexcludesfewerbiddertypestha...

展开>> 收起<<
Never Say Never Optimal Exclusion and Reserve Prices with Expectations-Based Loss-Averse Buyers Benjamin BalzerAntonio Rosato.pdf

共30页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:30 页 大小:544.19KB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-02

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 30
客服
关注