
Furthermore, the optimal public reserve price varies with the number of bidders. Indeed, the
more bidders are present, the less optimistic each of them is about her chances of winning, which
reduces their attachment. Yet, this does not imply that the reserve price always increases in the
number of bidders. Indeed, when raising the reserve price, the seller forgoes the attachment effect
of the marginal type. However, with already many bidders participating, adding an extra one
reduces this cost, leading to more exclusion.6With risk aversion, instead, the optimal reserve
price (in the FPA) is decreasing in the number of bidders; see Vasserman and Watt (2021).
The fact that the attachment effect does not operate on those bidders excluded by a public
reserve price suggests that a seller could raise an even higher revenue by exposing more bidders
to this effect. In Section 4 we show that this intuition is correct. In particular, we characterize
two tactics whereby a seller can expose almost all bidders to the attachment effect, resulting in a
strictly larger revenue than an auction with a public reserve price.
In Subsection 4.1 we show that secret and random reserve prices are revenue superior to public
and deterministic ones. To see why, notice that with a secret reserve price each bidder type expects
to win the auction with strictly positive — albeit potentially arbitrarily small — probability. In
such an auction, therefore, every bidder is exposed to potential losses and thus has an incentive
to bid more aggressively in order to avoid them. Hence, by transforming the public reserve price
into a secret one, the seller can ensure that every bidder experiences the attachment effect, which
enhances revenue. By doing so, however, the seller also reduces the competitive pressure on the
buyers’ side, which could potentially harm revenue since those low-type bidders excluded under a
public reserve would be participating now. Yet, the seller can choose a distribution for the (secret)
reserve price that puts large probability mass on relatively high prices and arbitrarily small mass on
low ones. Such a distribution ensures that, while the seller exposes every bidder to the attachment
effect, the competitive pressure is almost the same as under a public reserve price.
Thus, expectations-based loss aversion provides a novel rationale for secret and random reserve
prices.7This result is reminiscent of those in Heidhues and K˝oszegi (2014) and Hancart (2022),
who characterize the optimal pricing strategy for a monopolist selling to an expectations-based
loss-averse buyer. In line with the findings of Azevedo and Gottlieb (2012), who showed that risk-
neutral sellers benefit from offering gambles to consumers exhibiting prospect-theory preferences,
these papers find that the monopolist benefits from using random prices. In particular, Heidhues
and K˝oszegi (2014) show that if the seller has sufficient commitment power, a stochastic pricing
have been proposed. These include correlated types (Levin and Smith, 1996), interdependent values (Quint, 2017;
Hu et al., 2019), endogenous entry (McAfee, 1993; Levin and Smith, 1994; Peters and Severinov, 1997), bidders’
selection neglect when sellers are privately informed about the quality of the objects they sell (Jehiel and Lamy,
2015), level-k bidders (Crawford et al., 2009) and taste projection (Gagnon-Bartsch et al., 2021).
6Menicucci (2021) obtains a similar result in the classical IPV risk-neutral model when the bidders’ virtual values
are not monotone; in contrast, our result holds also for the regular case of increasing virtual values.
7An indirect way of implementing a secret and random reserve price is via “shill bidding”, a prominent albeit
often illegal practice in real-world auctions whereby a dummy buyer submits pre-specified bids on behalf of the
seller; see Ashenfelter (1989).
3