relates to the literature analyzing the effects of ranking algorithms on democratic outcomes. This literature
encompasses communication scholars (Hargittai, 2004; Granka, 2010; Napoli, 2015), computer scientists (Cho et
al., 2005; Menczer et al., 2006; Pan et al., 2007; Glick et al., 2014; Flaxman et al., 2016; Bakshy et al., 2015;
Liao et al., 2017; Tabibian et al., 2020), economists (Levy and Razin, 2019; Germano and Sobbrio, 2020; van
Gils et al., 2020; Acemoglu et al., 2022), legal scholars (Goldman, 2006; Grimmelmann, 2009; Sunstein, 2009),
media activists (Pariser, 2011), psychologists (Epstein and Robertson, 2015), political scientists (Putnam, 2001;
Hindman, 2009; Lazer, 2015; Tucker et al., 2018), and sociologists (Tufekci, 2015, 2018).
2 The Model
At the center of the model is a digital platform characterized by its ranking algorithm, which ranks and directs
individuals to different news items (e.g., websites, Facebook posts, tweets), based on the popularity of individuals’
choices. Such news items may be used by individuals to obtain information on an unknown cardinal state of the
world θ∈R(e.g., net benefits of vaccines, consequences of inaction on global warming, optimal foreign policy
intervention, etc.). The ranking of each news item is inversely related to its popularity, where the popularity is
determined by the number of clicks and the number of “highlights” received by a given item (e.g., likes received
by a Facebook post/number of shares, like/retweets of a tweet, etc.). Each click has a weight of one, and each
“highlight” has an additional weight of η≥0. In the following subsections we provide a formal and detailed
description of the different elements of our model.
2.1 News items and Individuals
There are M > 2 news items, each of which carries an informative signal on the state of the world ym∈R,
and which is drawn randomly and independently from N(θ, σ2
y) (we use g(y) to denote the corresponding density
function). There are Nindividuals, each of whom receives a private informative signal on the state of the world
xn∈R, which is drawn randomly and independently from N(θ, σ2
x) (we use f(x) to denote the corresponding
density function).
To model individuals’ clicking behavior, we further assume there is a benchmark b
θ∈R—non-informative
with respect to θ—which allows individuals to sort news items into “like-minded” or not. That is, we assume
that, leaving aside the order of news items provided by the ranking algorithm, individuals are able to see whether
a news item is reporting a “like-minded” information or not. Yet they need to click on the news item in order
to see the actual signal ym. This assumption is meant to capture a rather typical situation, where individuals
observe the “coarse” information provided in the landing page by the platform (e.g., infer the basic stance of a
news item, whether Left or Right, pro or anti something, from the website title, Facebook post intro, first tweet
in a thread, etc.), yet, in order to learn the actual content of the news (i.e., the cardinal signal ym) and update
her beliefs, the individual has to click on the news item.
We formally translate this setting into assuming that an individual is able to observe whether her own
signal xnand the news items’ signals ymare above or below b
θ. Accordingly, for each individual, the signal xn
has an associated binary signal indicating whether such signal is above or below b
θ: sgn(xn)∈ {−1,1}, where
sgn(xn) = −1 if xn<b
θand sgn(xn) = 1 if xn≥b
θ. Similarly, for each news item, the signal ymhas an associated
binary signal sgn(ym)∈ {−1,1}, where sgn(ym) = −1 if ym<b
θand sgn(ym) = 1 if ym≥b
θ.
From this we can compute M−and M+as the set of news items with binary signal respectively −1 and
1 (by slight abuse of notation, we also use M−and M+to denote the number of news items in M−and M+
respectively).
That is, given the individual’s signal xn, the benchmark b
θallows the individual to sort news items into
“like-minded” or not before actually clicking or reading. For most of the paper, we focus on the case where the
4