
however with non-negative measure-valued processes rather than function-valued ones.
In the sequel, we shall omit “non-negative” and only use “measure” for “non-negative
measure”.
There are many mathematical motivations to deal with this kind of processes. In
general, measure-valued processes are often used for modeling dynamical systems for
which the spatial structure plays a significant role. In the current setting, time to maturity
takes the role of the spatial structure. This is similar to common forward curve modeling
via stochastic partial differential equation (SPDE) as for instance in Benth and Kr¨uhner
(2014) or Benth et al. (2021b). The potential advantage of using measure-valued processes
instead of function-valued ones is that many spatial stochastic processes do not fall into
the framework of SPDEs. In addition, it is often easier to establish existence of a measure-
valued process rather than of an analogous SPDE, say in some Hilbert space, which would
for instance correspond to its Lebesgue density, but which does not necessarily exist.
The decisive economic reason for using measure-valued processes in electricity and
gas modeling however lies in the very nature of the future contracts, namely as products
that deliver the underlying commodity always over a certain period instead of one fixed
instance in time. To formulate this mathematically, denote the price of a future with
delivery over the time interval (τ1, τ2] at time 0 ≤t≤τ1by F(t, τ1, τ2). Then, following
Benth et al. (2008), F(t, τ1, τ2) can be written as a weighted integral of instantaneous
forward prices f(t, u) with delivery at one fixed time τ1< u ≤τ2, i.e.
F(t, τ1, τ2) = Zτ2
τ1
w(u, τ1, τ2)f(t, u)du, (1.1)
where w(u, τ1, τ2) denotes some weight function. The crucial motivation for measure-
valued process now comes from the fact that there is no trading with the instantaneous
forwards f(t, u) for obvious reasons. Thus, rather than using f(t, u)du in the expression
of the future prices, we can also use a measure.
An additional motivation stems from the empirically well documented fact that energy
spot prices can jump at predictable times, e.g. due to maintenance works in the power grid
or political decisions which currently influence these markets substantially. In the context
of such stochastic discontinuities we refer to the pioneering work Fontana et al. (2020)
in the setup of multiple yield curves. To illustrate why these predictable jumps lead to
measure-valued forward processes, consider the simple example where the spot price S
exhibits a jump at the deterministic time t∗. In this case we can write Su=e
Su+J{u≥t∗}
for some jump-size Jwhich is supposed to be Ft∗-measurable1and some process e
Sthat we
suppose for simplicity to be continuous. As the instantaneous forward price is according
to (Benth et al.,2008, equation (1.6)) given by
f(t, u) = EQ[Su|Ft] = EQ[e
Su+J{u≥t∗}|Ft] = EQ[e
Su|Ft] + EQ[J|Ft]{u≥t∗},
for each t < t∗< T and u∈[t, T ], this implies that u7→ f(t, u) is discontinuous at
u=t∗. As forward curve modeling requires to take derivatives with respect to u, the
corresponding SPDE contains a differential operator and we thus have to deal with dis-
tributional derivatives, leading naturally to measure-valued processes that can be treated
1Here, (Ft)0≤t≤Tdenotes some filtration supporting the spot price process and T > 0 some finite
time horizon.
3