1.Introduction
Decentralized Finance (DeFi) encodes the logic of traditional financial systems and benefits from
characteristics inherited from the underlying blockchain infrastructure. However, decentralization, as
the most controversial virtue of DeFi, is often questioned. Recently, Carapella et al. (2022) argue that
DeFi is not immune from centralized governance, and associate problems may arise.
The most popular mode of governance in DeFi is Decentralized Autonomous Organization (DAO),
proposed by Jentzsch (2016). In DAO, there is no centralized coalition, and any suggested changes to
DAO should be jointly decided by DAO members. To distribute decision-making power, DAO will
usually issue governance token, which are tradable cryptocurrency. Voters’ decision-making power
relies on the amount of governance token, and the proposal that gets most voting power will be
implemented. Benefiting from the transparency and accuracy of blockchain, voting results are
publicly visible and hard to be tampered, and DAO has been the most widely adopted choice for on-
chain governance.
Unfortunately, governance centralization is an inevitable problem for DAO. First, blockchain itself
is not safe haven for decentralization. Buterin (2021), as the co-founder of Ethereum blockchain,
proposes that complete decentralization is impossible if blockchain pursues scalability and securities
at the same time. In fact, a few key developers propose most changes to blockchain (Hsieh et al., 2017;
Yermack, 2017), implying that these developers have more control. Furthermore, DAO is not immune
from governance centralization. By investigating voting history of several leading DAO, DAO
governance is controlled by several dominant voters, and their centralized power has complicated
influence (Sun, Stasinakis and Sermpinis, 2022; Fritsch, Müller and Wattenhofer, 2022;). For example,
Carter and Jeng (2021) contend that key decision-makers, especially administrative teams can abuse
their governance power. Using Decentraland as a case study, Goldberg and Schär (2023) prove that
centralized governance may result in rent extraction behavior and other problems. Moreover, Nadler
and Schär (2020) show that some DAO participants may conceal their centralized decision-making
power by creating multiple on-chain identities.
The previous studies mainly focus on centralization problems at individual level, however, DAO
governance is likely to be battlefield of voter coalitions with different interests. Given the fact that
voting is all about social choice functions (Arrow, Sen and Suzumura, 2011; Kelly, 1988; Plott, 1976;
Schwartz, 1986), voters with similar interests and characteristics can form coalitions (Downs, 1957;
Black, 1990; Enelow and Hinich, 1994; Tajfel and Turner, 2004), while voters with different beliefs
will vote against each other (Adams, Merrill and Grofman, 2005; Abramson et al., 2009). In corporate
finance, voting rights are distributed among shareholders, and both small shareholders and large
shareholders can form their own coalitions. Smaller shareholders collaborate in order to protect their
own rights (Bennedsen and Wolfenzon, 2000; Zwiebel, 1995), while large shareholders attempt to
extract private benefits by seizing more control (Bennedsen and Wolfenzon, 2000; Dyck and Zingales,