THE LOCAL TO UNITY DYNAMIC TOBIT MODEL ANNA BYKHOVSKAYA AND JAMES A. DUFFY Abstract. This paper considers highly persistent time series that are subject to nonlin-

2025-05-06 0 0 806.31KB 42 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
THE LOCAL TO UNITY DYNAMIC TOBIT MODEL
ANNA BYKHOVSKAYA AND JAMES A. DUFFY
Abstract. This paper considers highly persistent time series that are subject to nonlin-
earities in the form of censoring or an occasionally binding constraint, such as are regularly
encountered in macroeconomics. A tractable candidate model for such series is the dynamic
Tobit with a root local to unity. We show that this model generates a process that converges
weakly to a non-standard limiting process, that is constrained (regulated) to be positive.
Surprisingly, despite the presence of censoring, the OLS estimators of the model parameters
are consistent. We show that this allows OLS-based inferences to be drawn on the overall
persistence of the process (as measured by the sum of the autoregressive coefficients), and for
the null of a unit root to be tested in the presence of censoring. Our simulations illustrate
that the conventional ADF test substantially over-rejects when the data is generated by a
dynamic Tobit with a unit root, whereas our proposed test is correctly sized. We provide an
application of our methods to testing for a unit root in the Swiss franc / euro exchange rate,
during a period when this was subject to an occasionally binding lower bound.
Keywords: non-negative time series, dynamic Tobit, local unit root, unit root test.
1. Introduction
Since the 1950s nonlinear models have played an increasingly prominent role in the analysis
and prediction of time series data. In many cases, as was noted in early work by Moran (1953),
linear models are unable to adequately match the features of observed time series. The efforts
to develop models that enjoy the flexibility afforded by nonlinearities, while retaining the
tractability of linear models, have subsequently engendered an enormous literature (see e.g.
Fan and Yao, 2003; Gao, 2007; Chan, 2009; and Terasvirta et al., 2010).
An important instance of nonlinearity arises when data is bounded by, truncated at, or
censored below some threshold, since such phenomena cannot be adequately captured – even
approximately – by a linear model. Many observed series are bounded below by construction,
and may spend lengthy periods at or near their lower boundary, such as unemployment rates,
prices, gross sectoral trade flows, and nominal interest rates. The non-negativity of interest
rates, and the resulting constraints that this may impose on the efficacy of monetary policy,
has received particular attention in recent years, as central bank policy rates have remained
at or near the zero lower bound for a significant portion of the past two decades, across many
economies (see e.g. Mavroeidis, 2021, and the works cited therein).
A tractable model for such series, which generates both their characteristic serial dependence
and censoring, is the dynamic Tobit model. In its static formulation, the model originates
We thank T. Bollerslev, G. Cavaliere, V. Kleptsyn, S. Mavroeidis, and seminar participants at Cambridge,
Cyprus, Duke, NES30 Conference, St Andrews, and Oxford for their helpful comments and advice on earlier
drafts of this work.
1
arXiv:2210.02599v3 [econ.EM] 8 May 2024
2 ANNA BYKHOVSKAYA AND JAMES A. DUFFY
with Tobin (1958). In its dynamic formulation, the model typically comes in one of two
varieties, which we refer to as the latent and censored models. In the latent dynamic Tobit, an
unobserved process {y
t}follows a linear autoregression, with yt= max{y
t,0}being observed;
whereas in the censored dynamic Tobit, {yt}is modelled as the positive part of a linear function
of its own lags, and an additive error (see e.g. Maddala 1983, p. 186, or Wei 1999, p. 419).
In both models the right hand side may be augmented with other explanatory variables.
Relative to the latent model, the censored model has the advantage of being Markovian,
which greatly facilitates its use in forecasting. It has also been successfully applied to a range
of censored series, in both purely time series and panel data settings, including: the open
market operations of the Federal Reserve (Demiralp and Jord`a, 2002; de Jong and Herrera,
2011); household commodity purchases (Dong et al., 2012); loan charge-off rates (Liu et al.,
2019); credit default and overdue loan repayments (Brezigar-Masten et al., 2021); and sectoral
bilateral trade flows (Bykhovskaya, 2023). Recently, Mavroeidis (2021) proposed the censored
and kinked structural VAR model to describe the operation of monetary policy during periods
when the zero lower bound may occasionally bind on the policy rate. If only the actual interest
rate (rather than some ‘shadow rate’) affects agents’ decision making, as assumed in closely
related work by Aruoba et al. (2022), then the univariate counterpart of this model is exactly
the censored dynamic Tobit.
The present work is concerned with the censored, rather than the latent, dynamic Tobit
model. As discussed by de Jong and Herrera (2011, p. 229), the censored model is arguably
more appropriate in settings where yt= 0 results not from limits on the observability of
some underlying y
t, but from an economic constraint on the values taken by yt. For example,
Bykhovskaya (2023, Supplementary Material, Appendix A) justifies the application of the
dynamic Tobit with reference to a game-theoretic model of network formation, in which the
zeros correspond to corner solutions of a constrained optimisation problem, i.e. where zeros
are systematically observed because of a non-negativity constraint on agents’ choices. In our
illustrative empirical application, to an exchange rate that is subject to a floor engineered by
a central bank (Section 5), the most recent values of the exchange rate are taken as sufficient
to describe the market equilibrium, and thus the conditional distribution of future rates. Our
focus on the censored model is also motivated by relatively greater need for the development of
relevant econometric theory in this area. In the latent model, the dynamics are simply those
of the latent autoregression, and so are readily understood by standard methods; whereas
in the censored model, the censoring affects the dynamics of {yt}in a non-trivial manner,
making the analysis rather more challenging. Indeed, establishing the stationarity or weak
dependence of the censored dynamic Tobit is far from trivial, as can be seen from Hahn and
Kuersteiner (2010), de Jong and Herrera (2011), Michel and de Jong (2018), and Bykhovskaya
THE LOCAL TO UNITY DYNAMIC TOBIT MODEL 3
(2023). Henceforth, all references to the ‘dynamic Tobit’ are to the censored version of the
model.1
Motivated in part by recent work on modelling nominal interest rates near the zero lower
bound, our concern is with the application of this model to series that are highly persistent,
so that above the censoring point they exhibit the random wandering that is characteristic
of integrated processes. The appropriate configuration of the dynamic Tobit model for such
series, in which the autoregressive polynomial has a root local to unity, has not been considered
in the literature to date – apart from the special case of a first-order model with an exact unit
root, as in Cavaliere (2004) and Bykhovskaya (2023). Our results are thus entirely new to the
literature.
Our principal technical contribution, within this setting, is to derive the limiting distri-
butions of both the standardised regressor process, and the ordinary least squares (OLS)
estimates of the parameters of the dynamic Tobit, when that model has an autoregressive
root local to unity. The reader may find our focus on OLS surprising, as this method would
usually provide inconsistent estimates in the presence of censoring. However, it turns out that
in our setting consistency (for all model parameters) is restored, and we obtain a usable limit
theory for the estimated sum of the autoregressive coefficients, which conventionally provides
a measure of the overall persistence of a process (cf. Andrews and Chen, 1994; Mikusheva,
2007). While one may contemplate alternatively using maximum likelihood (ML) or least
absolute deviations (LAD) to estimate the model, OLS enjoys the advantages of maintain-
ing only weak distributional assumptions on the innovations (unlike ML), and avoiding the
numerical minimisation of a non-convex criterion function (unlike LAD).
Our asymptotics provide the basis for practical unit root tests for highly persistent, censored
time series. Motivated by our finding that OLS is consistent, we consider a test based on
the (constant only) augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) tstatistic, but which employs critical
values modified to reflect the censoring present in the data generating process. We show,
via Monte Carlo simulations, that as our critical values are larger than the conventional ADF
critical values, their use eliminates the significant over-rejection that may result from the naive
application of the ADF test to censored data. (This tendency to over-reject the null of a unit
root appears typical of models that incorporate unit roots and nonlinearities, having been also
found by e.g. Hamori and Tokihisa, 1997; Kim et al., 2002; and Wang and De Jong, 2013.)
Strikingly, the distribution of tstatistic, under censoring, is stochastically dominated by that
obtained from the linear autoregressive model.2
1de Jong and Herrera (2011) alternatively refer to this model as a ‘dynamic censored regression’, but the term
‘dynamic Tobit’ appears more commonly in the literature (see e.g. Hahn and Kuersteiner, 2010; Michel and
de Jong, 2018; Bykhovskaya, 2023).
2This holds only with respect to the distributions: it is not true that if one simulates a linear and a Tobit
model with the same underlying innovations, then the former tstatistic will always be larger than the latter.
4 ANNA BYKHOVSKAYA AND JAMES A. DUFFY
Our work may be construed, more broadly, as extending the analysis of highly persistent
time series, and the associated machinery of unit root testing, from a linear setting to a
nonlinear setting appropriate to time series that are subject to a lower bound. In doing so,
we complement the seminal work of Cavaliere (2005), which similarly sought to extend this
machinery to the setting of bounded time series. Our contribution is to effect this extension
within a class of nonlinear autoregressive models that have been widely applied to censored
time series (as evinced by the works cited above), and which fall outside his framework.
On a technical level, the most closely related works to our own are those of Cavaliere (2004,
2005) and Cavaliere and Xu (2014), who develop the asymptotics of what they term ‘limited
autoregressive processes’ with a near-unit root, which are (one- or two-sided) non-Markovian
censored processes constructed by the addition of regulators to a latent linear autoregression.
While their (one-sided) model has a superficial resemblance to the dynamic Tobit, there are
important, but subtle differences between the two (see Section 2.4 for a discussion). Perhaps
the most striking similarity is that both models, in the case of an exact unit root, give rise
to processes that converge weakly to regulated Brownian motion; but when roots are merely
local to unity, the limiting processes associated with these two models are distinct (see the
discussion following Theorem 3.1).
Convergence to regulated Brownian motions has also been obtained previously in the set-
ting of first-order threshold autoregressive models with an (exact) unit root regime and a
stationary regime, as considered by Liu et al. (2011) and Gao et al. (2013). However, allowing
for both near-unit roots and higher-order autoregressive terms introduces technical challenges
that require us to take a markedly different approach from those employed in these earlier
works. With respect to higher-order models, a major difficulty relates to the treatment of the
differences {yt}. In a linear autoregressive model with a single unit root, and all other roots
outside the unit circle, these would follow a stationary autoregression; but in our setting they
instead follow a regime-switching autoregression, where the regime depends on the (lagged)
level of yt, and so are inherently non-stationary. Accoridingly, standard arguments for con-
trolling the magnitude of ∆yt, and deriving the limits of functionals thereof, are unavailing.
We provide a striking example in which ∆ytis explosive even though all but one of the autore-
gressive roots (the root at unity) lie outside the unit circle, due to the interactions between
the two autoregressive regimes (see Appendix C). To preclude such cases, we develop a condi-
tion relating to the joint spectral radius of the autoregressive representation for ∆yt, which is
sufficient to control the magnitude of ∆ytand plays an essential role in our arguments. (This
concept has been previously employed in the context of stationary autoregressive models, see
e.g. Liebscher (2005); Saikkonen (2008).)
The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 discusses the model and
our assumptions. Asymptotic results and corresponding tests are derived in Section 3, while
supporting Monte Carlo simulations are shown in Section 4. Section 5 applies our framework
THE LOCAL TO UNITY DYNAMIC TOBIT MODEL 5
to the exchange rate between the Swiss franc and the euro during a period when this rate was
subject to a lower bound. Finally, Section 6 concludes. All proofs appear in the appendices.
Notation. C,C,C′′, etc. denote generic constants that may take different values in different
parts of this paper. All limits are taken as T→ ∞ unless otherwise specified. p
and d
respectively denote convergence in probability and distribution (weak convergence). We write
XT(r)d
X(r) on D[0,1]’ to denote that {XT}converges weakly to X, where these are
considered as random elements of D[0,1], the space of cadlag functions on [0,1], equipped
with the uniform topology. For p1 and Xa random variable, Xp:= (E|X|p)1/p.
2. The dynamic Tobit model with a near-unit root
2.1. Model and assumptions. Consider a time series {yt}generated by the dynamic Tobit
model of order k1, written in augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) form,3
(2.1) yt="α+βyt1+
k1
X
i=1
ϕiyti+ut#+
, t = 1, . . . , T,
where ∆yt:= ytyt1, and [x]+:= max{x, 0}denotes the positive part of xR. Let
(2.2) B(z) := 1 βz (1 z)
k1
X
i=1
ϕizi= (1 β)z+ (1 z)ϕ(z),
where ϕ(z) := 1 Pk1
i=1 ϕizi. We impose the following on the data generating process (2.1).
Assumption A1.{yt}is initialised by (possibly) random variables {yk+1, . . . , y0}. Moreover,
T1/2y0
p
b0for some b00.
Assumption A2.{yt}is generated according to (2.1), where:
1. {ut}tZis independently and identically distributed (i.i.d.) with Eut= 0 and Eu2
t=σ2.
2. α=αT:=T1/2aand β=βT= exp(c/T )for some a, c R.
Assumption A3.There exist δu>0and C < such that:
1. E|ut|2+δu< C.
2. E|T1/2y0|2+δu< C, and E|yi|2+δu< C for i∈ {−k+ 2,...,0}.
Figure 2.1 displays a typical sample path for the dynamic Tobit (2.1), under the preceding
assumptions.
3The autoregressive form is yt= [α+Pk
i=1 βiyti+ut]+, where β1=β+ϕ1,βk=ϕk1, and βi=ϕiϕi1
for i∈ {2, . . . , k 1}. In particular β=Pk
i=1 βicorresponds to the sum of the autoregressive coefficients.
摘要:

THELOCALTOUNITYDYNAMICTOBITMODELANNABYKHOVSKAYAANDJAMESA.DUFFYAbstract.Thispaperconsidershighlypersistenttimeseriesthataresubjecttononlin-earitiesintheformofcensoringoranoccasionallybindingconstraint,suchasareregularlyencounteredinmacroeconomics.AtractablecandidatemodelforsuchseriesisthedynamicTobit...

展开>> 收起<<
THE LOCAL TO UNITY DYNAMIC TOBIT MODEL ANNA BYKHOVSKAYA AND JAMES A. DUFFY Abstract. This paper considers highly persistent time series that are subject to nonlin-.pdf

共42页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!

相关推荐

分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:42 页 大小:806.31KB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-06

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 42
客服
关注