Vulnerabilities of Single-Round Incentive Compatibility in Auto-bidding Theory and Evidence from ROI-Constrained Online Advertising Markets Juncheng Li and Pingzhong Tang

2025-04-26 0 0 3.07MB 24 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
Vulnerabilities of Single-Round Incentive Compatibility in Auto-bidding: Theory
and Evidence from ROI-Constrained Online Advertising Markets
Juncheng Li and Pingzhong Tang
Tsinghua University
{lijuncheng13, kenshinping}@gmail.com
Abstract
Most of the work in the auction design literature
assumes that bidders behave rationally based on
the information available for every individual auc-
tion, and the revelation principle enables designers
to restrict their efforts to incentive compatible (IC)
mechanisms. However, in today’s online advertis-
ing markets, one of the most important real-life ap-
plications of auction design, the data and compu-
tational power required to bid optimally are only
available to the platform, and an advertiser can only
participate by setting performance objectives and
constraints for its proxy auto-bidder provided by
the platform. The prevalence of auto-bidding ne-
cessitates a review of auction theory. In this pa-
per, we examine the markets through the lens of
ROI-constrained value-maximizing campaigns. We
show that second price auction exhibits many un-
desirable properties (computational hardness, non-
monotonicity, instability of bidders’ utilities, and
interference in A/B testing) and loses its domi-
nant theoretical advantages in single-item scenar-
ios. In addition, we make it clear how IC and
its runner-up-winner interdependence contribute to
each property. We hope that our work could bring
new perspectives to the community and benefit
practitioners to attain a better grasp of real-world
markets.
1 Introduction
Auto-bidding has become a corner stone of modern adver-
tising markets. For better end-to-end performance and cus-
tomer experience, platforms now provide algorithmic agents
to set fine-grained bids for advertisers, who only need to sub-
mit campaign-level optimization objectives and constraints.
As a result, the community has seen a surge of publications
on auto-bidding in recent years.
One of the most notable features of the auto-bidding
paradigm is the change of roles played by advertisers and
platforms. Traditionally advertisers are assumed to bid ratio-
nally for each individual ad slot, and thus the real-time bid-
ding (RTB) literature focuses on developing algorithms for
advertisers to maximize their objectives subject to different
constraints and auction rules, while the auction design liter-
ature, anticipating the best response of advertisers or RTB
algorithms, explores new auction rules to optimize various
goals of the platform. However, in auto-bidding markets,
most of the technical components are under the management
of the platform: auto-bidders provided by the platform will
compete with each other, based on valuations predicted by
the platform, under auction rules that are also designed by
the platform. Such a greater control over the market imposes
a more diverse set of requirements upon the designer. The
auction design literature has long been focusing on incentive
compatibility and welfare/revenue guarantee, but the desider-
ata of an auto-bidding mechanism are far beyond these two.
Google AdSense’s partial shift at 2021 from second to first
price auction1might serve as an exemplary demonstration of
this perplexity.
Despite the evolution of ecosystems, first and second price
auction remain as the dominant mechanisms used in practice.
In this paper, we study the mathematical model abstracted
from real-world first and second price auction markets with
ROI-constrained auto-bidders. In addition to theoretic inter-
ests, our work are also motivated by real-world observations.
Traditional interpretations of some phenomena may confuse
both sides of the market and lead to business choices detri-
mental in the long run. Our goal is thus to develop a deeper
understanding of auto-bidding at the market scale, and pro-
vide practitioners a more holistic view to facilitate decision
making. We will show, through a series of theoretical and em-
pirical results, that the dominant advantage of second price
auction over first price is, in many regards, reversed in the
world of auto-bidding. It will be made clear throughout the
journey how IC, instead of simplifying the reasoning of both
bidders and auctioneers, unnecessarily complicates the game
in a profound way.
1.1 ROI-Constrained Auto-bidding Markets and
Related Works
Previously much effort was spent on the study of auto-bidders
with budget constraints [Karande et al., 2013; Charles et
al., 2013; Balseiro and Gur, 2019; Gao and Kroer, 2020;
1In November 17, 2021, Google moves the AdSense auction for
Content, Video, and Games from second price auction to first price,
while keeping Search and Shopping as before [Google, 2021].
arXiv:2210.06107v6 [cs.GT] 11 May 2024
Chen et al., 2021a; Balseiro et al., 2021b; Conitzer et al.,
2022a; Conitzer et al., 2022b], but Return-on-Investment
(ROI), another widely adopted auto-bidding option, received
much less attention until very recently [Golrezaei et al., 2021;
Balseiro et al., 2021c; Deng et al., 2021]. For campaigns
with ROI-constraints, advertisers should submit either a tar-
get ROI, a target Return-on-Ad-Spend or a target Cost-
per-Action (tROI/tROAS/tCPA).2The objective of the auto-
bidder is then to maximize the acquired value while keep-
ing the average spend for each unit of value below the target
threshold. ROI-constrained auto-bidders are dominating in
market share in many regions of the world. There is also re-
cent empirical evidence [Golrezaei et al., 2021]from Google
AdX that advertisers are indeed ROI-constrained.
An advertiser’s value for an ad slot (to which we will refer
as a generic good throughout the rest of the paper) is typi-
cally given by the product of the conversion-rate (predicted
by the platform) and the value of each conversion. For ROI-
constrained campaigns, the latter part is the amount of money
that the advertiser is willing to pay the platform for each
(unit of) conversion.2Truthful bidding for each individual
auction is ex-post optimal for non-constrained quasi-linear
utility-maximizing bidders. But for ROI-constrained value-
maximizers, it is possible to raise bids above values to win
more while keeping the average spend of each conversion be-
low the threshold. In this paper, auto-bidders will take values
as given and be restricted to the multiplicative pacing strat-
egy,2wherein the bids of each bidder could only be generated
through scaling the values for all goods by a common mul-
tiplier of its choice. There is always a multiplier that is ex-
post bidder-optimal in second price auction, and the strategy
is one of the most implemented in the industry regardless of
auction formats (in particular, it remains popular in first price
auction3).
Table 1 positions our market model within the growing lit-
erature on auto-bidding. Existing works differ in the mod-
eling of advertisers’ valuations and utilities. Traditionally
the valuation of each bidder is modeled as being drawn
from a stochastic process independently of each other. We
adopt a framework first studied by Conitzer et al. [2022b;
2022a], where the valuation is given as the (fixed) input and
can be viewed as a discretized density function or a real-
ized sample of an arbitrary joint distribution. In particular,
the correlation prevalent in advertising can thus be captured.
For utilities, previous research mainly focuses on budget-
constraints, and our paper complements the recent line of
work on ROI-constraints. Babaioff et al. [2021]also con-
sider ROI, but they model bidding behaviors with respect to
the marginal ROI of each individual auction rather than the
average ROI across.
Deng et al. [2021]and its follow-up work [Balseiro et al.,
2021a]study a model that largely coincide with ours. Their
goal is to design mechanisms having revenue and welfare
2See Appendix B for more notes on terminology.
3Possibly surprisingly, we will show in Section 6 that it will not
bring incentive issues for first price auction and it is in the interests
of a platform to enforce so. In contrast, both bidders and sellers have
incentives to deviate from it in second price auction (Appendix J.3).
guarantees when the designer has fairly accurate signals on
the valuation. Though we will also report some results on rev-
enue and welfare, we emphasize that, for today’s large scale
auto-bidding systems, auction (combined with auto-bidding
strategies) acts more like an efficient distributed algorithm
to match demand with supply and compute market-clearing
prices. With this mentality, our work covers a broader range
of properties and focuses heavily on their possible practical
impacts on advertisers and platforms. We also differ in the
adopted solution concept. We allow fractional allocation and
incorporate the tie-breaking rule into the solution concept,
which is not only well-motivated, but also guarantees the ex-
istence of equilibrium even though the market is discrete and
discontinuous. In contrast, Balseiro et al. [2021a]break ties
lexicographically and more complex auctions like VCG and
GSP are considered there. So they choose a weaker solution
concept called undominated bids and avoid the discussion of
existence. Nonetheless, this distinction diminishes for large
markets as the result of a single auction becomes negligible.
Auto-bidding or RTB algorithms have been studied for a
long time. Such works typically assume a stationary environ-
ment and optimize various objectives for a single advertiser.
They fail to capture other bidders’ responses invoked by the
action of the focal agent, and the resulting equilibrium out-
come may not fulfill the initial design goal if all the bidders
implement the same strategy (see, e.g., Appendix L.1). One
notable exception is the work by Aggarwal et al. [2019], who
were aware of this problem and tried to prove the existence of
an equilibrium. But their treatment of equilibrium is incom-
plete (see a discussion in Appendix C).
Researchers have shown that the computation of equilib-
rium bears some inherent hardness with budget-constrained
multiplicative pacing bidders. For computing any equilib-
rium, we improve previous result to show that it is PPAD-
hard to approximate within constant parameters (for budget-
constraints, it was shown to be hard to approximate within
polynomially small parameters [Chen et al., 2021a]). Our re-
sult is built on a more concise reduction quite distinct from
the previous one. We also improve the NP-hardness result of
optimizing revenue/welfare [Conitzer et al., 2022b]to APX-
hardness. Moreover, the source of these hardness and the vul-
nerabilities of IC are demonstrated more clearly with our con-
structions, which we believe could help both researchers and
practitioners better extrapolate our techniques and insights.
1.2 Single-round Incentive Compatibility
The classic revelation principle ensures us that, when design-
ing single-item auctions, any implementable allocation rule
could be implemented in an incentive compatible way by di-
rectly eliciting bidders’ private information (in most cases
only the valuations to the item to be sold are needed). By
focusing on IC mechanisms, the designer loses nothing while
bidders could be prevented from strategic behaviors. In com-
parison, the characterization and computation of equilibrium
in first price auction is notoriously hard (see, e.g., [Filos-
Ratsikas et al., 2021]and the survey therein).
Though second price auction is only IC for single-item
auctions, it possesses another fascinating property in auto-
bidding markets: from a single bidder’s perspective, each in-
Utility model Valuations
Deterministic, correlated Stochastic, independent
ROI-constrained
value-maximizer
Our model, Balseiro et al. [2021a]Balseiro et al. [2021c], Golrezaei et al.
[2021]
Budget-constrained utility-
maximizer
Conitzer et al. [2022a; 2022b], Chen et al.
[2021a], Gao and Kroer [2020]
Balseiro and Gur [2019], Balseiro et al.
[2021b]
ROI&budget-constrained
value-maximizer
Deng et al. [2021], Aggarwal et al. [2019]
Table 1: Common auto-bidder types and valuation assumptions in the literature.
dividual auction comes with a winning price independent of
its own bid (which is essentially an equivalent statement of
IC). As a consequence, the (ex-post/offline) task of each auto-
bidder is a linear program for bidders with linear constraints
like ROI and budget. The optimal solution can be well ap-
proximated by the multiplicative pacing strategy, which is
simple to implement and performs well even in the online
setting [Balseiro and Gur, 2019; Balseiro et al., 2022]. This
provides second price auction an illusory strategyproofness
that could be called ex-post IC: every advertiser could truth-
fully report its tROI and happily accept the equilibrium bids
given by its proxy auto-bidder as deviating unilaterally will
not bring extra profit at the moment.
Nonetheless, even long before the advent of the auto-
bidding era, experiments have revealed that bidders’ behav-
iors in second price auction are far from truthful (see, e.g.,
[Kagel and Levin, 2011]). Recall that, in second price auc-
tion, the price is set by the runner-up, but paid by the winner.
In some senses, both the winner and the runner-up care lit-
tle about the absolute magnitudes of their own bids: only the
ranking (first and second) is important. This can also be seen
from the linear program optimizing utility for the auto-bidder
(see, e.g., [Aggarwal et al., 2019]), where no decision vari-
able denoting bids appears and the solution only prescribes
whether each auction should be won or not. However, the bid
of the runner-up always means a lot to the winner. A well-
known enemy of IC due to this runner-up-winner interdepen-
dence is externality, i.e., the utility of a bidder depends on the
allocation and payment of not only itself, but also others.
It should not be surprising that externality makes manip-
ulation worthwhile since IC is not designed for the job. In
our auto-bidding markets, the objective of each auto-bidder
is defined clearly without externality.4However, auto-bidders
adjust bids based on the overall performance across all auc-
tions. Even though at equilibrium changing bids unilaterally
could not benefit the manipulator immediately, it may trigger
a cascade of responses that shift the whole market state. This
creates a kind of externality that is internalized into the out-
come of the shifted equilibrium. It is worthwhile to point
out that, for some results in this paper, it seems to be the
multiplicative pacing strategy that leads to a property. Actu-
ally it is irrelevant of the specific bidding strategy or even the
4Another common scenario where IC fails is that bidders do not
have complete knowledge of their valuations. This is not an issue
either in our case.
ROI-constraint: for simultaneous auctions with single-round
IC, bidders will always bid strategically across all auctions,5
which is enough to establish those results.
Letting the (bids of) opponents determine the payment of
the winner is the key to establish IC for single-item auctions,
but it is also the key to open the Pandora’s box in auto-bidding
markets, as will be detailed in the remainder of this paper.
1.3 Contributions
In this paper, we consider the auto-bidding market where
ROI-constrained value-maximizing bidders compete with
each other in simultaneous auctions. Our main focus is sec-
ond price auction: behaviors of auto-bidders within first price
auction markets will be discussed at the very end.
We start by formulating our own solution concept of the
market (and its approximate version), named auto-bidding
equilibrium, since a pure Nash equilibrium may not always
exist. The equilibrium reasonably captures the expected
steady-state that the auto-bidders intend to reach collectively,
and its guaranteed existence puts our study on a solid theoret-
ical footing. Our most important results are as follows:
It is PPAD-hard to find an approximate auto-bidding
equilibrium within constant parameters.
It is APX-hard to optimize revenue or welfare over all
auto-bidding equilibria.
Non-monotonicity: an advertiser who raises its
tROI/tROAS (or equivalently, lowers the tCPA) at the
equilibrium could end up with a higher revenue after de-
viation (through a natural equilibrium transition process
to resolve multiplicity).
Besides their own significance, the constructions used in es-
tablishing these results reveal many crucial structures of the
market and highlight the role played by IC. They serve as the
foundation to comprehend and interpret other characteristics
of the market.
We proceed to explore several practical concerns of great
consequence. For advertisers, we show that the market suf-
fers severe utility instability and input sensitivity issues. For
platforms, we demonstrate that biases exist broadly in the
widely-used A/B testing. Finally, we give a comprehensive
comparison between first and second price auction, and show
5Even a non-constrained utility-maximizer could manipulate if
one of its opponents has constraints. Truthful reporting is secure
only when all the other bidders are insensitive to each other’s bid.
that first price auction is generally exempted from the above
undesirable properties and performs better. As an application
of our results, we give our guess about why Google AdSense
moves from second to first price auction in a partial manner.
2 Markets and Equilibria
We consider a market where a set of bidders N={1, . . . , n}
compete for a set of divisible goods M={1, . . . , m}. With-
out loss of generality, the tROIs of all bidders are set to
zero (equivalently, tROAS of one),6i.e., each bidder’s spend
should be no more than its acquired value. We use vi,j to de-
note the value of bidder ito good j. For each good j, there
is at least one bidder isuch that vi,j >0. The platform si-
multaneously runs a single-item second price auction for ev-
ery good. Auto-bidders are restricted to apply multiplicative
pacing strategies: the action space of bidder iis the set of
undominated multipliers αi[1, A],7and its bid for good j
is αivi,j . Multiplicative pacing is ex-post bidder-optimal, as
shown in Proposition 1. The omitted proof follows from a lin-
ear programming formulation of the ROI-constrained value
maximization problem, and the result is widely known in both
the literature and the industry.
Proposition 1. Suppose that bidders can bid arbitrarily
across auctions. Holding all other bidders’ bids, each bidder
has a best response wherein bids are generated by scaling its
valuations of all goods by a uniform multiplier, given that it
could freely choose to win any fraction of a good of which it
is a tied winner.
To complete the picture, one’s first intuition may be to
specify a tie-breaking rule, make the allocation x[0,1]n×m
(where xi,j is the fraction of good jallocated to bidder i)
uniquely determined by α, define bidder’s utility as the ROI-
constrained valuation:
ui(α) = Pjxi,j vi,j ,if Pjxi,j pjPjxi,j vi,j ;
−∞,otherwise;
and study the pure Nash equilibrium (PNE) of the game.
However, in Appendix D, we will give an example where, no
matter how ties are broken, a PNE does not exist. On closer
inspection, we find that the steady-state of the market can be
captured instead by the solution concept defined below.
Definition 1. An auto-bidding equilibrium (α, x)consists of
multipliers α[1, A]nand allocation x[0,1]n×msuch
that
bidders with the highest bid win the good: if xi,j >0,
αivi,j = maxkαkvk,j for all i, j;
winner pays the second price: if xi,j >0, then pj=
maxk̸=iαkvk,j for all i, j;
full allocation of goods: Pixi,j = 1 for all j;
ROI-feasible: Pjxi,j pjPjxi,j vi,j for all i;
6See Appendix D on why this is WLOG. Later we may some-
times change the tCPA of a bidder by a factor λ, by which we mean
all the valuations of this bidder is scaled by λ.
7Fixing other bidders’ bids, αi= 1 always weakly dominates
any αi<1. The cap Acan safely be replaced by +for most
cases. See more discussion in Appendix D.
maximal pacing: unless αi=A,Pjxi,j pj=
Pjxi,j vi,j for all i.
The auction rules and ROI-constraints are directly imposed
by the first four conditions, while the best responses among
bidders are encoded in the maximal pacing condition in a less
straightforward way. To see this, note that, from bidder is
perspective, given the winning price of each good, αiacts
as a marginal-ROI threshold: it will win all goods in whole
with a marginal ROI strictly larger than 1
αi1and lose those
with ROI strictly lower. At any auto-bidding equilibrium, if
αi>1,αi(and the resulting vector of bids with bi=αivi,j )
is exactly a best response since the marginal ROI of any good
lost or tied is strictly lower than zero, and winning anymore
will definitely violate the ROI-constraint. If, however, αi= 1
and bidder iis only allocated a fraction of some good as in
the example given in Appendix D, αiis technically not a best
response (for the normal form game) but the maximal pac-
ing condition is still satisfied. For such bidders, their oppo-
nents could always oscillate their multipliers around the equi-
librium point to achieve the corresponding stable allocation.
Theorem 1. An auto-bidding equilibrium always exists.
The proof is in Appendix F. In addition, the definition and
existence result can be extended to incorporate reserve prices
and additive boosts (see Appendix E), both of which are com-
mon practice in the industry.
The relaxed version of the equilibrium, named (η, δ)-
approximate auto-bidding equilibrium, is defined as follows:
bidders with bids close enough to the highest can win
the good: if xi,j >0,αivi,j (1 η) maxkαkvk,j (if
there is a reserve price rj, winner’s bid should also be
no less than (1 η)rj);
winner pays the second price (even if it is the bidder
with the second highest bid; if there is a reserve price,
the price is the maximum of the reserve price and the
second price);
full allocation of goods;
• approximately ROI-feasible: Pjxi,j pj(1 +
δ)Pjxi,j vi,j for all i;
• approximately maximal pacing: unless αi=A,
Pjxi,j pj(1 δ)Pjxi,j vi,j for all i.
3 Computational Complexities
In this section, we demonstrate two different kinds of in-
tractability or unpredictability of the market. Our first result
shows that, in general, it is hard for a market to reach a sta-
ble state. But even for cases where an equilibrium is easy to
achieve, the difference among equilibria may be large, and the
second result tells us that, in general, it is hard to determine
how large the difference is.
At a high level, the interdependence that the (bid of)
runner-up determines the payment of the winner endows the
market with a structure similar to Boolean operators (elec-
tronic components and conductive wires). In digital electron-
ics, a functionally complete set of operators can be assembled
goods w1w2w3u¯u
input bidder w11/14
input bidder w21/14
input bidder w31/14
gate bidder u1/3 1/3 1/3 1/2 1/4
reserve price 1/7 1/7 1/71 1
Table 2: Valuation profile to encode gate u.
to compute any Boolean function. In our model, it is PPAD-
hard to find an equilibrium since it can encode any stable
state of a circuit that is continuous. When optimizing revenue
or welfare, the circuit structure collapses to discrete choices
that correspond to equilibrium selection, and the problem be-
comes NP-hard (and APX-hard since the correspondence is
almost exact). Note that hardness does not only exist in the
family of instances constructed in the reduction: for a gen-
erally hard problem, it is possible but usually non-trivial to
identify a meaningful subset of instances that are computa-
tionally tractable.
Our focus here is the many complex structures brought into
the market by IC. Nonetheless, to explore equilibrium proper-
ties quantitatively, we develop two algorithms (see Appendix
I for details) to compute equilibrium. Their own properties
are beyond the scope of this paper.
3.1 Complexity of Finding Any Equilibrium
Theorem 2. It is PPAD-hard to find an (η, δ)-approximate
auto-bidding equilibrium for some constant η, δ > 0.
The full proof is in Appendix G. We will use equilibria
in a properly constructed market to encode feasible states
of a circuit, which is one of the most fundamental and fre-
quently used objects in complexity theory [Chen et al., 2009;
Rubinstein, 2018]. Papadimitriou and Peng [2021]show that
a circuit consisting only of a continuous version of NAND
(NOT-AND) gate is enough to capture PPAD-hardness, in
analogy to the functional completeness of NAND gate in dig-
ital electronics. The continuous gate computes the function
that sums all (at most 3) inputs and inverts the result: for a
gate u, given all the input values ywof its incoming gates
wNu, its own value yushould satisfy that
yu
{0},if PwNuyw>0.5;
{1},if PwNuyw<0.5;
[0,1],otherwise.
An assignment yof values to gates is feasible if the above
constraints are satisfied for all gates. The key construction of
our reduction is given in Table 2. (This is a simplified version:
in the full proof we will remove the reliance on reserve prices
and take approximation into account.) We will associate each
gate uwith a bidder of the same name and use its multiplier
αuto encode the gate’s value yu(with yu=αu/21). The
valuation profiles are calibrated such that bidder uwould al-
ways win all input goods w1, w2, w3but at varying prices,
determined by (multipliers of) their corresponding input bid-
ders. The correspondence between bidder uand gate uis
almost straightforward:
If the sum of input prices is too high, to satisfy its ROI-
constraint, bidder ucould not even win good uin whole
and thus won’t raise αuabove 2.
If the sum is too low, good ¯uis required to satisfy bidder
us appetite for more valuation, which forces αuto be
fixed at 4.
If input prices sum to exactly 0.5, bidder ucan freely
choose αuas long as it is allocated uin whole but not ¯u
at all.
Intuitively, the hardness of finding a feasible state of a cir-
cuit lies in the coordination among the interconnected gates.
Given any value assignment, for each unsatisfied gate u, the
corresponding αuin the constructed market is either too large
(input goods are too expensive and ROI-constraint is violated)
or too small (input goods are too cheap and bidder uhas the
incentive to win ¯u). Consider hypothetically that we apply a
naive search algorithm8where, for each non-equilibrium as-
signment y, we choose some unsatisfied u, lower αuby a
small amount if it is too large, and raise it if it is too small.
As we adjust αu(or yu) for a bidder (gate), the payments
(sums of inputs) of its outgoing neighbors change accord-
ingly, which may also change their directions of adjustment
(e.g., a bidder goes from ROI-feasible to infeasible). As gates
can be assembled arbitrarily, we can imagine how hard it is to
find a state that satisfies the constraints of all bidders/gates.
In retrospect, IC requires the payment of the winner to be
determined externally by other bidders. As a result, nothing
is local in the market and we can connect bidders in a way
that encodes any circuit perfectly. You may think that the
market constructed in the reduction can be simplified, e.g.,
by setting a reserve price for the input good such that its price
would no longer be affected by the input bidder and an equi-
librium could be easier to find. However, this requires much
knowledge of the specific market a priori such as an upper
bound of a bidder’s multiplier, which is typically impossible.
In general markets, the aforementioned chasing behavior is
even more complex: e.g., if a gate bidder lowers its multiplier,
the consequence is simply lowering payments for its outgo-
ing neighbors and increase their ROIs, but in general markets
it may also lose goods it previously won and instead decrease
ROI for the opponent who now wins the item with a negative
marginal ROI. See the non-monotonicity instance in Section
4 for an example of this complex cascading phenomenon.
3.2 Complexity of Finding Revenue or Welfare
Optimal Equilibrium
Theorem 3. It is APX-hard to find the optimal revenue or
welfare over all auto-bidding equilibria.
8Theoretically, any problem in PPAD can be reduced to the
generic End-Of-The-Line problem (by which the class is defined),
where we are given (1) a directed graph consisting solely of non-
intersecting directed paths (lines) and (2) a vertex with no predeces-
sor (the start of a line). The task is to find a vertex with no successor
(the end of a line). There is a natural algorithm (inevitably ineffi-
cient if PPAD ̸=P) that simply searches along any path. The search
procedure we depict here shares a similar spirit, but it may (or may
not) circulate and is only used to give some intuition.
摘要:

VulnerabilitiesofSingle-RoundIncentiveCompatibilityinAuto-bidding:TheoryandEvidencefromROI-ConstrainedOnlineAdvertisingMarketsJunchengLiandPingzhongTangTsinghuaUniversity{lijuncheng13,kenshinping}@gmail.comAbstractMostoftheworkintheauctiondesignliteratureassumesthatbiddersbehaverationallybasedonthei...

展开>> 收起<<
Vulnerabilities of Single-Round Incentive Compatibility in Auto-bidding Theory and Evidence from ROI-Constrained Online Advertising Markets Juncheng Li and Pingzhong Tang.pdf

共24页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:24 页 大小:3.07MB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-04-26

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 24
客服
关注