THE EFFECT OF FEAR ON TWO SPECIES COMPETITION Vaibhava Srivastava1 Eric M. Takyi2and Rana D. Parshad1 1Department of Mathematics

2025-05-06 0 0 2.54MB 42 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
THE EFFECT OF “FEAR” ON TWO SPECIES COMPETITION
Vaibhava Srivastava 1, Eric M. Takyi 2and Rana D. Parshad 1
1)Department of Mathematics,
Iowa State University,
Ames, IA 50011, USA.
2)Department of Mathematics and Computer Science,
Ursinus College,
Collegeville, PA 19426, USA.
Abstract. Non-consumptive effects such as fear of depredation, can strongly
influence predator-prey dynamics. These effects have not been as well studied
in the case of purely competitive systems, despite ecological and social moti-
vations for the same. In this work we consider the classic two species ODE
and PDE Lokta-Volterra competition models, where one of the competitors
is “fearful” of the other. We find that the presence of fear can have several
interesting dynamical effects on the classical scenarios of weak and strong com-
petition, and competitive exclusion. Notably, for fear levels in certain regimes,
we show bi-stability between interior equilibrium and boundary equilibrium
is possible - contrary to the classical strong competition situation where bi-
stability is only possible between boundary equilibrium. Furthermore, in the
spatially explicit setting, the effects of several spatially heterogeneous fear
functions are investigated. In particular, we show that under certain L1re-
strictions on the fear function, a weak competition type situation can change
to competitive exclusion. Applications of these results to ecological as well as
sociopolitical settings are discussed, that connect to the “landscape of fear”
(LOF) concept in ecology.
1. Introduction
Fear, is defined as,
An unpleasant emotion caused by the belief that someone or some-
thing is dangerous [77].
It is a complex emotion, that is critical as a safety measure, and can trigger
the “fight or flight” response [2] - in particular it can change the way one acts,
even when there is no threat present [24]. In predator-prey systems, this is most
naturally observed among prey, due to their perceived threat of depredation [10].
This perception can lead to non-consumptive effects or trait-mediated interactions,
which are behavioral, morphological or physiological changes in prey phenotype, due
to this threat [23,10]. Such effects are known to strongly influence predator-prey
dynamics [21]. From a mathematical viewpoint, the effects of fear in predator-
prey systems has been intensely investigated since the seminal work of Brown et.
al. [28], where optimal foraging theory is extended to consider a game theoretic
setup, played out by predator and prey, exhibiting stealth and fear, in which an
animal follows a map or a “landscape of fear” (LOF), which describes its predation
risk while it navigates the physical landscape. In recent work, Wang et. al. [50],
model fear of depredation, as a (predator) density dependent effect, that negatively
effects the prey population. In essence, the prey’s growth rate is modeled as a
1
arXiv:2210.10280v1 [q-bio.PE] 19 Oct 2022
2 FEAR EFFECT
monotonically decreasing function of predator density. Dynamically, a key finding
in [50] is that under the parametric restrictions of a Hopf bifurcation, an increase
in the fear parameter (and prey’s birth rate parameter) can alter the direction
of a Hopf bifurcation from supercritical to subcritical. Thus, fear enables both
supercritical and subcritical Hopf bifurcations, contrary to only the supercritical
bifurcations found in classical predator-prey systems. In essence, the fear effect
can change the fundamental cylical patterns of predator-prey dynamics, leading to
large scale ecological consequences [12].
These results have since initiated a host of activities in diverse ecological sce-
narios such as when refuges are present [59,51], when the prey has tendencies to
avoid predators [52], or when the predators responses are influenced by interfer-
ence pressures, for instance, via a Beddington-DeAngelis functional response [60].
Various works have considered the fear effect in case of group defense by the prey
[65,64]. It has been investigated in the context of cooperative and competitive sys-
tems within the larger predator-prey context. These include the fear effect when
predators are cooperating [55] in the hunting process, or when they are hunting for
competing prey [14]. These effects have been investigated in the three and multi-
species settings as well [53,68] where fear can damp population explosions [71].
Various authors have considered the fear effect in a stochastic setting [70] as well
as a spatially explicit setting, in the context of taxis type movements, as well as
pattern formation [56,62]. It can also lead to chaotic dynamics [67]. However,
the effect of fear has been far less investigated in classical monotone systems, such
as purely cooperative or competitive two species systems - that are outside the
predator-prey setting.
Competition among two species, typically modeled via the Lotka–Volterra com-
petition model and its variants have been intensely investigated in the last few
decades. These models take into account growth and inter/intraspecific competi-
tion [41], and predict well-observed states in biology of co-existence, competitive
exclusion of one competitor, and bi-stability, and find diverse applications in ecol-
ogy and invasion science [13,15,3,6,1]. There are several ecological motivations
for competitors being fearful of each other. This is perhaps most naturally seen
to occur with intraguild predation - a widespread phenomenon in many food webs,
where competitors will kill and consume each other [7]. Recent evidence of non-
consumptive effects exerted by intraguild predator mites (Blattisocius dentriticus)
on their competitor (Neoseiulus cucumeris) show this can be an important factor
in determining food web dynamics in biological control [73,4]. However, there is
strong evidence for fear in purely competitive two species systems without preda-
tory effects. Barred owls (Strix varia) are a species of owl, native to eastern North
America. They have expanded their range westward over the last century and are
considered invasive in western North America. Currently, their range overlaps with
the spotted owl (Strix occidentalis), which is native to the north west and western
North America. This has resulted in intense competition between the two species
[72]. Barred owls exert a strong negative influence on spotted owls, threatening
their possible competitive exclusion [75]. Field observations report frequent barred
owl attacks on spotted owls, and even on surveyors imitating spotted owl calls
[74]. There is also evidence of barred owls aggressively chasing spotted owls out of
FEAR EFFECT 3
shared habitat - but not the opposite [76]. Such evidence clearly motivates consid-
ering fear type dynamics into a purely competitive two species model where one of
the competitors is fearful of the other.
There are also several socio-economic-political settings, where pure competitors
may be fearful of each other. Small/new businesses may be fearful of large busi-
nesses, due to their already large market share [43]. But large business may also
be fearful of small local businesses, due to their familiarity with local nuances, that
may yield competitive advantage at a small local scale [42]. Fear is also conceiv-
able among two competing political parties, where the weaker party on a national
scale, may have a stronger voter bank at a regional scale [18]. Or perhaps two war-
ring drug cartels, where the weaker cartel has certain local/territorial strongholds
[19,44] - within which they might be able to induce fear among the stronger cartel
[19]. Such phenomenon becomes even more interesting in the spatially explicit case
where this fear could be heterogeneous in the spatial domain of interest. This con-
nects back to the LOF concept, where the fear function is essentially the map that
describes how the fear levels change as a species disperses over a physical landscape.
Motivated by all of the affore mentioned sociopolitical, economic as well as eco-
logical settings, the current manuscript considers the effect of fear in a competitive
two species system. We restrict our analysis to the case where only one of the
competitors is fearful of the other. Our investigations show that:
Sufficiently large fear can change a situation of competitive exclusion, to a
strong competition type scenario, where there is bi-stability between bound-
ary equilibrium. See Fig. 5(C). Dynamically, this occurs via a transcritical
bifurcation. This is shown via Lemma 2.19, see Fig. 9.
Fear in a certain parametric regime can change a situation of competitive
exclusion to bi-stability between boundary equilibrium and interior equilib-
rium, see Fig. 4and Fig. 5(B). Dynamically, this occurs via a saddle-node
bifurcation. This is shown via Lemma 2.18, see Fig. 8. This is in sharp
contrast with classical competition theory, where bi-stability occurs only
between boundary equilibriums.
Sufficiently large fear can change a situation of weak competition to a com-
petitive exclusion type scenario. This is shown via Lemma 2.5, see Fig. 2.
Fear cannot qualitatively change a strong competition type scenario. This
is shown via Lemma 2.8, see Fig. 3. Also, fear cannot produce periodic
orbits. This is demonstrated via Lemma 2.10.
In the spatially explicit setting, comparison theory is used to determine
point-wise restrictions on the fear functions such that competitive exclu-
sion or strong competition type dynamics abounds. These are shown via
Theorem 3.8, Theorem 3.10 and Theorem 3.15, see Figs. [10,11,13].
In the spatially explicit setting, fear can change a situation of weak com-
petition to a competitive exclusion type scenario, for fear functions with
certain L1restrictions. This is shown via Theorem 3.13 and Lemma 3.14,
see Figs. [15,16,17]. In particular the fear functions need not lie uniformly
above the critical fear levels derived in the ODE case via Lemma 2.5.
Various heterogeneous fear functions are constructed to demonstrate these
results numerically, see Fig. 18b. Applications of these to ecological as well
as socio-political settings are discussed in section 4.
4 FEAR EFFECT
2. The ODE case
2.1. Model formulation. Consider the classical two species Lotka-Volterra ODE
competition model,
(1)
du
dt =u(a1b1uc1v),
dv
dt =v(a2b2vc2u),
where uand vare the population densities of two competing species, a1and a2are
the intrinsic (per capita) growth rates, b1and b2are the intraspecific competition
rates, c1and c2are the interspecific competition rates. All parameters considered
are positive. The dynamics of this system are well studied [20]. We recap these
briefly,
E0= (0,0) is always unstable.
Eu= (a1
b1,0) is globally asymptotically stable if a1
a2
>max b1
c2
,c1
b2.
Herein uis said to competitively exclude v.
Ev= (0,a2
b2) is globally asymptotically stable if a1
a2
<min b1
c2
,c1
b2. Herein
vis said to competitively exclude u.
E=a1b2a2c1
b1b2c1c2,a2b1a1c2
b1b2c1c2exists when b1b2c1c26= 0. The positivity of
the equilibrium holds if c2
b1<a2
a1<b2
c1and is globally asymptotically stable
if b1b2c1c2>0. This is said to be the case of weak competition.
If b1b2c1c2<0, then E=a1b2a2c1
b1b2c1c2,a2b1a1c2
b1b2c1c2is unstable as a saddle.
In this setting, one has initial condition dependent attraction to either
Eu(a1
b1,0) or Ev(0,a2
b2). This is the case of strong competition.
We proceed by considering the effects of fear on the classical model (1), when
one of the competitors is fearful of the other.
2.2. The case of vfearing u.We consider the case of the competitor vbeing
fearful of u. Thus in the classical model (1), we model the fear effect as in [50],
where the growth rate of the fearful competitor v, is not constant but rather density
dependent. Essentially, the growth rate is decreased by a factor 1
1+ku , where
k0 is a fear coefficient. Thus a higher density of the competitor uincreases the
fear in v. When k= 0, the assumption is there is no fear and one recovers the
classical model (1). If fear is present, we obtain the following ODE model for two
competing species uand v, where vis fearful of u.
du
dt =a1ub1u2c1uv,
dv
dt =a2v
1 + ku b2v2c2uv.
(2)
2.2.1. Existence. The nullclines associated with the problem (2) are
u(a1b1uc1v) = 0 and va2
1 + ku b2vc2u.
FEAR EFFECT 5
Hence, the boundary equilibrium points are obtained by substituting u= 0 and
v= 0 in the above equations of the nullclines, respectively. Denote the boundary
equilibrium points as b
E1= (0,0), b
E2= (a1
b1,0) and b
E3= (0,a2
b2).
For the interior equilibrium, substitute u=a1
b1c1
b1vin the second nullcline
equation, i.e.,
a2
1 + ka1
b1c1
b1vb2vc2a1
b1c1
b1
v= 0.
On simplification, we have that vsolves a quadratic equation of the form
A(v)2+Bv+C= 0, where
A=c1k(b2b1c1c2),
B=b1(c1c2b2b1)a1k(b2b12c1c2),
C=b1(a2b1a1c2)a2
1c2k.
(3)
Let
(4) v
1,2=B±B24AC
2A
be the two roots of above qudratic equation. WLOG assume v
1< v
2.Moreover,
consider the following parametric restriction
b1(a1c2a2b1) + a2
1c2k < h(b2b1c1c2)(2a1kb1)a1kc1c2ia1
c1
.(5)
We can prove the existence of a positive equilibrium point b
E4with the choice of
specific parameters. Let us use Descartes’s rule of sign to establish some sufficient
conditions for the existence of one or two positive equilibrium points.
Two positive equilibrium points: Under the assumption A > 0, B < 0 and C > 0,
i.e., b2b1>2c1c2> c1c2and k < 1
a2
1c2b2
1a2a1c2b1,we have two positive roots.
In order to claim that these two roots correspond to two positive interior equilibria,
we need some extra assumption given by:
v
1< v
2:= B+B24AC
2A<a1
c1
=⇒ −C < (Aa1
c1
+B)a1
c1
.
Hence, if b1(a1c2a2b1) + a2
1c2k < [(b2b1c1c2)(2a1kb1)a1kc1c2]a1
c1,we have
two positive interior equilibrium points b
E4= (u
i, v
i) for i= 1,2.
One positive equilibrium point: Under the assumption A > 0, B < 0, i.e.,
b2b1>2c1c2> c1c2, we have at least one positive root of the quadratic equa-
tion. If C < 0, which is k > 1
a2
1c2b2
1a2a1c2b1along with (5) gives existence
of one positive equilibrium point b
E4= (u, v). Moreover, if C > 0, which is
k < 1
a2
1c2b2
1a2a1c2b1, and v
1<a1
c1and v
2>a1
c1, then we have existence of one
positive equilibrium point b
E4= (u, v).
We formulate all these restrictions as an existence theorem:
Theorem 2.1. For the given ODE system (2), we always have three boundary
equilibrium points, namely b
E1:= (0,0),b
E2:= (a1
b1,0) and b
E3:= (0,a2
b2). For the
摘要:

THEEFFECTOF\FEAR"ONTWOSPECIESCOMPETITIONVaibhavaSrivastava1,EricM.Takyi2andRanaD.Parshad11)DepartmentofMathematics,IowaStateUniversity,Ames,IA50011,USA.2)DepartmentofMathematicsandComputerScience,UrsinusCollege,Collegeville,PA19426,USA.Abstract.Non-consumptivee ectssuchasfearofdepredation,canstrongl...

展开>> 收起<<
THE EFFECT OF FEAR ON TWO SPECIES COMPETITION Vaibhava Srivastava1 Eric M. Takyi2and Rana D. Parshad1 1Department of Mathematics.pdf

共42页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!

相关推荐

分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:42 页 大小:2.54MB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-06

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 42
客服
关注