Expectations Formation with Fat-tailed Processes Evidence from Sales Forecasts Eugene Larsen-HallockAdam RejDavid Thesmar

2025-05-06 0 0 2.54MB 34 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
Expectations Formation with Fat-tailed
Processes: Evidence from Sales Forecasts *
Eugene Larsen-HallockAdam Rej David Thesmar §
October 20, 2022
Abstract
We empirically analyze a large sample of firm sales growth expectations.
We find that the relationship between forecast errors and lagged revision is
non-linear. Forecasters underreact to typical (positive or negative) news about
future sales, but overreact to very significant news. To account for this non-
linearity, we propose a simple framework, where (1) sales growth dynamics
have a fat-tailed high frequency component and (2) forecasters use a simple
linear rule. This framework qualitatively fits several additional features of data
on sales growth dynamics, forecast errors, and stock returns.
*We thank seminar participants at CFM and Columbia GSB for their constructive feedback. Thesmar is a consultant for
CFM.
Columbia & CFM
CFM
§MIT, CEPR & NBER
1
arXiv:2210.10169v1 [q-fin.ST] 18 Oct 2022
1 Introduction
Expectations formation is a core question in economics. In recent years, a strain
of literature in macroeconomics and finance has been collecting empirical regulari-
ties using survey data on subjective forecasts. It finds that forecasts largely deviate
from the full information model that predominates in economic modelling: forecast
errors are biased and predictable using past errors and past revisions. Two types of
explanations for this have been put forward. The first one is that the data-generating
process (DGP) is simple and known to forecasters, but forecasting rules are irra-
tional but linear, featuring for instance under-reaction (Bouchaud et al., 2019) or
overreaction (Bordalo et al., 2019, 2020; Afrouzi et al., 2020). The second ap-
proach to explaining observed biases is the tenet that the data-generating process is
too complex to be known by forecasters. Thus, they use a misspecified model cali-
brated on the data they observe. This may come from the fact that the DGP is hard to
learn (for recent contributions along these lines see Kozlowski et al., 2020; Farmer
et al., 2022), or alternatively from bounded rationality of the forecasters. They can
only use simple forecasting rules (Fuster et al., 2010; Gabaix, 2018). In any case,
forecast errors are predictable because forecasters use an imperfect model. In this
paper, we find evidence consistent with the second view, i.e. that, facing complex
(non-Gaussian) processes, forecasters use simple rules.
We use data on some 63,601 analyst forecasts of corporate revenue growth and
their realizations. An advantage of focusing on revenue growth (instead of EPS as
the literature typically does) is that revenue is always positive so that growth rate is
always well defined. We first show that the relationship between forecast revisions
and future forecast error is non-linear, a feature that is not reported in the exist-
ing literature. In some settings, revisions linearly and positively predict forecast
errors, a feature commonly interpreted as evidence of under-reaction (Coibion and
Gorodnichenko, 2015a). In others, revisions linearly and negatively predict forecast
errors, which is considered as evidence of overreaction (Bordalo et al., 2019, 2020).
In our sample, which is much larger than the existing studies, and which focuses
on a rather new object, sales growth, we find evidence of both. For intermediate
values of revisions, forecasters underreact to news (an increasing relation between
2
revisions and errors). For large values of revisions, forecaster overreact (a decreas-
ing relation between revisions and errors). This non-linearity is robust. It holds in
U.S. data and international data. It holds across most industry groups.
The remainder of the paper is dedicated to explaining this fact. Our framework
is based on the simple assumption that forecasters use a linear rule to forecast sales
growth, but that this rule is misspecified because the true DGP is more complex.
Taking inspiration from the literature on firm size distribution (in particular, Axtell,
2001; Bottazzi and Secchi, 2006), we posit that sales growth distribution may be
modelled by the sum of a low-frequency and high-frequency shock. The low fre-
quency shock is Gaussian, while the high-frequency shock is non-Gaussian. It may
have a very large (positive or negative) realizations. With such a model, the optimal
forecast of future growth, conditional on current growth, is non-linear. A perfectly
rational forecaster anticipates more reversion to the mean when realizations are ex-
treme and more persistence when realizations are intermediate. We assume, how-
ever, that agents stick to a linear rule to make their forecasts. The fact that agents
use a misspecified model may be grounded in bounded rationality (i.e., agents use a
simple rule even if the process is complex, as in Fuster et al., 2010) or the difficulty
of learning about complex processes (shocks with multiple frequencies are hard to
learn Farmer et al., 2022; shocks with fat tails also Kozlowski et al., 2020).
Combined, these two assumptions (linear forecasting rule but short-term non-
Gaussian shocks) are enough to generate the non-linear relation between forecast er-
rors and past revisions that observe empirically. The mechanism is intuitive. When
revisions are large, the rational forecaster should anticipate mean reversion, but the
linear forecaster won’t. She overreacts to big positive (or negative) news. When
fitting her forecasting rule to the data, she does, however, take this overreaction into
account, and optimally attenuates the sensitivity of her forecast to recent observa-
tions in the bulk of the distribution. As a result, she underreacts to news of lesser
significance.
We then qualitatively test four additional predictions of the model. We start with
two natural predictions of the data-generating process. The first such prediction
is that the distribution of sales growths has fat tails, a fact that holds strongly in
3
the data (and previously shown by Bottazzi and Secchi, 2006). In particular, we
check that this fact is not driven by an alternative model of firm dynamics, where
firms have heterogeneous volatility, but Gaussian dynamics. In such a setting, large
growth shocks could be generated by the subset of firms who are more volatile than
average (Wyart and Bouchaud, 2003). We thus rescale sales growths by estimates
of firm-level standard deviation and find that the resulting distribution still has very
fat tails, suggesting that growth shocks occur within firms, not across firms.
The second prediction from our DGP is that, conditional on past growth, fu-
ture growth should follow a S-shaped pattern as discussed above. We show that
this holds in the data, whether we normalize sales growth by firm-level standard
deviation or not.
The third prediction is on forecast errors. A natural prediction of our forecasting
model is that the autocorrelation of forecast errors should have the same non-linear
relation as the relation between errors and lagged revision. In our model, where
the forecasting rule is linear, they are the same. Large past errors are equivalent
to big shocks and therefore transient ones: This leads to overreaction, as in the
error-revision relation. We find that this pattern holds in the data: forecast error
are positively correlated for intermediate values and negatively for large absolute
values.
Our fourth and last prediction is on stock returns. Assuming risk-neutral pricing
and that equity cash-flows follow a dynamic similar to revenues, it is easy to show
that our model predicts that the autocorrelation of returns should have a shape simi-
lar to the autocorrelation of forecast errors. For intermediate values of past returns,
momentum should dominate, but for extreme values of returns, stock returns should
mean revert. We find this pattern to hold in the data. Our findings line up with re-
cent research from Schmidhuber (2021), who also finds evidence of momentum for
“normal past returns” and mean-reversion for extreme values of returns. We con-
clude from this analysis that the risk-adjusted performance of momentum strategies
would be considerably improved by excluding stocks whose past returns have been
large in absolute value.
This paper contributes to the recent empirical literature on expectations for-
4
mation. Most papers in this space focus on linear and Gaussian data-generating
processes. Forecasting rules may, or may not, be optimal, but are in general linear,
so that the relationship between forecast errors and past revisions (or past errors)
is also linear. Our paper emphasizes the non-linearity of such a relation, and as
a result, suggests an different modelling approach for the data-generating process
to account for this non-linearity. We emphasize non-Gaussian dynamics in firms’
growth (as Kozlowski et al., 2020, have done in a different setting and in their case
with a focus on Bayesian learning).
In doing this we also connect the expectations formation literature with the em-
pirical literature on firm dynamics, which has since Axtell (2001) emphasized the
omnipresence of power laws in the distribution of firms sizes (see Gabaix, 2009, for
a survey of power laws in economics). That sales growths (rather than log sales)
have fat tails is a less well-known fact, although it was first uncovered by Bottazzi
and Secchi (2006).
Last, our assumption that forecasters use a simple, linear, forecasting rule that
is misspecified is inspired by the literature on bounded rationality, which assumes
economic agents have a propensity to use oversimplified models to minimize com-
putation costs (Fuster et al., 2010, 2012; Gabaix, 2018). Such models are correct
on average, they are fitted on available data, but their misspecification gives rise to
predictability in forecast errors.
Section 2 describes the data we use: publicly available data on analyst forecasts
(IBES) and confidential data on international stock returns from CFM. Section 3
documents the main fact: future errors are a S-shaped function of past revision.
Section 4.1 lays out the simple framework that we build in order to explain this
novel pattern. Section 5 tests four additional predictions from this model. Section
6 concludes.
5
摘要:

ExpectationsFormationwithFat-tailedProcesses:EvidencefromSalesForecasts*EugeneLarsen-Hallock†AdamRej‡DavidThesmar§October20,2022AbstractWeempiricallyanalyzealargesampleofrmsalesgrowthexpectations.Wendthattherelationshipbetweenforecasterrorsandlaggedrevisionisnon-linear.Forecastersunderreacttotypic...

展开>> 收起<<
Expectations Formation with Fat-tailed Processes Evidence from Sales Forecasts Eugene Larsen-HallockAdam RejDavid Thesmar.pdf

共34页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!
分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:34 页 大小:2.54MB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-06

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 34
客服
关注