EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE YOSHIHIRO SHIRAI University of Maryland College Park Department of Mathematics

2025-05-06 0 0 1.38MB 30 页 10玖币
侵权投诉
EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE
YOSHIHIRO SHIRAI
University of Maryland, College Park, Department of Mathematics
Abstract. Dynamic spectral risk measures define a claim’s valuation bounds as supremum
and infimum of expectations of the claim’s payoff over a dominated set of measures. The
measures at which such extrema are attained are called extreme measures. We determine
explicit expressions for their Radon-Nykodim derivatives with respect to the common dom-
inating measure. Based on the formulas found, we estimate the extreme measures in two
cases. First, the dominating measure is calibrated to mid prices of options and valuation
bounds are given by options bid and ask prices. Second, the dominating measure is esti-
mated from historical mid equity prices and valuation bounds are given by historical 5-day
high and low prices. In both experiments, we find that the market determines upper bounds
by testing scenarios in which losses are significantly lower than expected under the domi-
nating measure, while lower bounds by ones in which gains are only slightly lower than in
the base case.
1. Introduction
Much of the existing literature on continuous time valuation bounds defines upper and
lower prices as suprema and infima of conditional expectations of discounted payoffs over a
certain set Mof measures. When Mis weakly compact and the bounds are time consistent,
the extrema are attained at the same measure at different points in time (Delbaen (2006)).
We call such measures extreme for analogy with those analyzed in Cherny (2008) in a static
setting. The main mathematical contribution of this paper is to construct a pair of extreme
measures for the continuous time Conic Finance bounds defined in Madan et al. (2017).1
The fundamental assumption of Conic Finance, introduced in Madan & Cherny (2010),
is that risks cannot be fully hedged and so the set of trades deemed acceptable by market
operators must strictly contain that of arbitrages. Acceptability is defined in Conic Finance
by assuming that the market chooses a reference probability space (Ω,F,Q) and a set of test
measures Mdominated by Q, so that a payoff is acceptable if its expected value under any
test measure is nonnegative. Other definitions include those of Ledoit (1995), Cochrane &
Sa`a-Requejo (2000), Cherny & Hodges (2000) and Bernardo & Ledoit (2000). Furthermore,
valuation bounds can also be defined based on indifference pricing (see Carmona (2008)) and
model-free hedging (Hobson (1998)).
E-mail address:yshirai@umd.edu.
Date: October 23, 2023.
2020 Mathematics Subject Classification. 60H10, 60G51, 91G20, 91G80.
Key words and phrases. Backward Stochastic Differential Equations, Convex Analysis, Conic Finance,
Dynamic Spectral Risk Measures, Empirical Analysis of Bid-Ask Spreads.
1The point of view in Madan et al. (2017) is that of risk measures, whereas here it is on valuation
bounds. The mathematical aspects of the two theories are the same (see e.g. Jashcke & Kuchler (2001)).
1
arXiv:2210.13671v2 [q-fin.RM] 20 Oct 2023
2 EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE
Each of these alternatives presents its own advantages. As explained in Madan & Cherny
(2010), Conic Finance valuations are independent from agents’ preferences and initial wealth
and they are robust to model misspecifications. In addition, generating upper and lower
prices in Conic Finance does not require the existence of underlying liquid securities.
From a mathematical perspective, upper and lower valuations are defined in continuous
time Conic Finance as the unique solutions of respective upper and lower backward stochas-
tic differential equations (BSDEs) driven by a Choquet integral and with pure jump Levy
generator X(see Madan et al. (2017)). In this case, and to the author’s knowledge, a full
proof for general formulas identifying the Radon-Nikodym derivatives of a pair of extreme
measures Qand Qwith respect to Qis absent from the literature. This paper’s mathemat-
ical contribution is then Theorem 3.3, in which such an explicit expression is provided in
terms of the level sets of the control processes Zand Zof the upper and lower BSDEs.
By the formulas obtained, the bounds defined by continuous time Conic Finance are no
longer linear, as in static Conic Finance, over a pair of comonotonic payoffs. The requirement
for linearity is now that the control processes associated to the value of the two claims be
comonotonic for all t[0, T ], where Tis the expiration date, and we show in Remark
4.3 that this is indeed more restrictive than just comonotonicity of payoffs. This is no
surprise: by Theorem 7.1 in Delbaen (2021), a comonotonic and time consistent dynamic
expectation on the set of bounded random variables must be a conditional expectation.
Another interesting consequence of our formulas is that, differently from the static case
(Kusuoka (2001)), continuous time Conic Finance valuations are not law invariant. More
precisely, as observed in Remark 4.4, equivalence of the valuation bounds of two claims
requires the L´evy measure of Xunder Qof the α-level sets of Ztand Ztto be the same
for each level αand all t[0, T ]. Such result is in line with the one proved in Kupper
& Schachermeyer (2009) that the only time consistent, law invariant, dynamic nonlinear
expectation is the entropic risk measure.
In our L´evy setting, the existence of the extreme measures implies that, as shown in Barles
et al. (1996), there are functions u, ℓ : [0, T ]×RD\{0} → Rsuch that u(t, Xt) and (t, Xt)
are the upper and lower valuations for each t[0, T ]. Furthermore, as shown in Denneberg
(1994), the bounds are Malliavin differentiable and so the control processes satisfy
(1.1) Zt(y) = u(t, Xt+y)u(t, Xt), Zt(y) = (t, Xt+y)(t, Xt)
for every t[0, T ]. Based on (1.1), we show in Theorem 4.2 that if Xhas dimension 1 and f
is monotone, the level sets of the control processes are time independent and deterministic,
and so Xis a L´evy process under Qand Q.
This result paves the way for two empirical studies that constitute the second and third
contributions of this paper. In the first such study, the law of Xunder the reference measure
Qis obtained by calibrating the bilateral gamma (BG) process introduced in Kuchler &
Tappe (2008) to mid prices of options on the SPY exchange trade fund (SPY). Since options’
payoffs are monotonic, Xis a L´evy process under the extreme measures associated to options’
valuation bounds, and the respective upper and lower L´evy measures can be calibrated to
bid and ask prices of options via FFT (see Carr & Madan (1998)). Our goals are:
1. to assess if continuous time Conic Finance bounds can match relative bid-ask spreads
across strikes; and
2. to infer, based on the different relative bid-ask spreads across strikes, which events
the market is more uncertain about.
EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE 3
The importance of 1. is that the calibration exercise determines the set Mof test measures.
If the relative options bid-ask spreads are matched, the same set Mcan be used to generate
quotes for certain derivatives traded out of the counter, such as straddles and, more in
general, combo options. This is an important issue for market makers as they need to quickly
provide quotes that are cheap but accurate enough. With this consideration in mind, we also
find conditions on the set Mfor Xto be a BG process under both extreme measures and
assuming it is a BG process under Q. The conditions obtained resemble the Wang transform
(Wang (2000), Wang (2002)), with the BG distribution replacing the Gaussian. When they
are enforced, calibration is further facilitated, although the error is higher (see Remark 5.5).
The importance of 2. is that the ability to explain why some events are more uncertain than
others based on market data is one way to assess the calibrated set M. We set X=GL,
where Gand Lare positive gamma processes referred to as gains and losses (see Kuchler &
Tappe (2008) for their existence). Then, we find that bounds are determined by distorting
the loss process Lfor the ask price of calls and the bid price of puts, and the process Gfor the
bid price of calls and ask price of puts. That is, a call’s ask and a put’s bid are determined
by testing their payoff under scenarios in which there is a high chance that LTis lower than
expected under Q. For a put’s ask or a call’s bid, instead, the payoff is tested against the
event that GTmay be higher than expected. We then find that the stress on the loss process
is higher than that on the gain process. This is related to the investors’ need to hedge against
economic downturns, which makes the out of the money (OTM) puts market more liquid
than that of OTM calls. Only few existing empirical studies are performed on options bid
and ask prices, so this contribution is quite unique in the empirical finance literature.
For the second empirical study of this paper we assume that, under the reference measure,
the law of Xis again BG but this time estimated from daily closing mid prices of the SPY.
Furthermore, the observed upper and lower valuations are defined by the SPY 5-day high
and low prices. This is based on the fact that large trades put in place by institutional
investors are often executed over a few days at least. The payoff of owning the SPY is
defined by Y0eXT, where Y0is the current value of the SPY and Tis 5 days. Then Xis
again a L´evy process under Qand Qand its L´evy measure can be expressed in terms of an
integral. Hence, the probability density of XTcan be calculated by Fourier inversion, and
estimated by matching its tail to that of the empirical distribution (as in Madan (2015)).
The resulting estimator is called the digital moment estimator (DM). Our goals are:
1. to compare the estimates we obtain from DM with the one obtained through the
generalized method of moment (GMM); and
2. to infer, based on historical equity prices, which events market operators are more
uncertain about.
The importance of 1. is to determine the usefulness of our formulas for the Radon-Nykodim
derivatives for estimation purposes. In fact, computation of the tail measure is a demanding
task without knowledge of the probability density of XT, prone to numerical error and
approximations. Hence, without the formulas developed in this paper, one is forced to use
methods, such as the GMM, that are not designed to incorporate in their estimates events
that occur less frequently. The importance of 2. is as in the study on options. We find that:
1. with DM estimators, and as found in our first study on options data, upper valuations
are determined by uncertainty in the loss process and lower valuations by uncertainty
in the gain process; GMM estimators are, instead, more balanced;
4 EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE
2. the drifts of the lower valuation process estimated by the two methods are similar;
however, the DM drift of the upper valuation is lower than the GMM one;
4. the correlation between the DM estimated upper drivers and upper returns is similar
to that between lower driver and lower returns; for GMM, it is substantially higher;
3. as in the case of calibration to options, the higher DM estimated upper driver implies
that the market tests scenarios in which losses are much lower than expected, and
gains only a bit higher; this appears related to the monetary authority’s support to
the financial sector and the real economy during the 2010-2020 decade;
5. the standard deviation of the upper valuation implied by DM estimators is higher,
on average, than that of the density of the lower valuation; they are similar for GMM
estimated densities.
From these observations we argue that market operators were more uncertain over the
period considered about the SPY’s loss process than its gain process. Furthermore, the
GMM fails to incorporate in its estimates extreme realizations of upper and lower returns.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we review Conic Finance valua-
tion bounds and prove preliminary results. The formula for the Radon-Nikodym derivatives
dQ/dQand dQ/dQis given in section 3. Section 4 considers the case of monotonic claims.
Results on numerical experiments are reported in Section 5 and 6. Section 7 concludes.
2. Assumptions and Preliminary Results
2.1. Assumptions. Unless otherwise specified, the following assumptions, most of which
are as in Madan et al. (2017), hold throughout the rest of the paper.
(i) Given a topological space (X, τ), B(X) denotes the Borel σ-algebra on X.
(ii) Given a measurable space (Ω,F), random processes Xi={Xi
t}t0on (Ω,F) and
constants Yi
0,i= 1, ..., D, and T > 0, we consider a market composed of a risk-free
asset with rate r0 and Drisky assets with payoff Yi
T:= Yi
0eXi
T. To simplify
notation, the rate ris normalized to zero, except in the empirical studies (Sections
5 and 6). Furthermore, we set X:= (X1, ..., Xn) and {Ft}t0denotes the right
continuous, completed filtration generated by X.
(iii) There is a probability measure Qon (Ω,F) such that, for each i,Yi
TL2(Ω,F,Q)
and the discounted process Yi={Yi
t}t0defined by Yi
t:= Yi
0ert+Xtis a martingale
under Q. This is a condition necessary to avoid arbitrages (Jouini & Kallal (1995),
Theorem 2.1).
(iv) The process Xsatisfies, for t0 and dRD\ {0},
Xt=dt+Z[0,t]×RD\{0}
y˜
N(dy, ds).
where ˜
N(dy, ds) := N(dy, ds)ν(dy)ds and Nis a Poisson random measure with
Q-compensator ν. It is assumed that νis σ-finite, has no atoms and, for some ε > 0,
ZRD\{0}
|y|2+εν(dy)RD\{0}.
(v) {Xt,x
s}stis defined for st0 and xRDby
Xt,x
s=x+d(st) + Z[t,s]×RD\{0}
y˜
N(dy, ds).
EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE 5
(vi) Γ = +,Γ) is a pair of measure distortions, i.e. Γ+,Γ: [0, ν(R)) R+are
bounded, concave and satisfy Γ(x)xand
Z(0(R))
Γ±(y)
2y3/2dy < .(2.1)
(vii) L2(ν) := L2(R\{0},B(R\{0}), ν) and g:L2(ν)Ris specified for zL2(ν) by
g(z) := Z
0
Γ+(ν(z+> a))da +Z
0
Γ(ν(z> a))da.(2.2)
Example 2.1. An example of measure distortions is the pair Λ = (Λ+,Λ)defined by
(2.3) Λ+(x) := a1ecx1/(1+γ),Λ(x) := b
c1ecx,
where x0,0< γ < 1,0< b 1and a, c > 0. These distortions are obtained in Eberlein
et al. (2013) by composing common probability distortions with the change of variable x
1ecx. Note that if γ1then assumption 2.1 does not hold, and if b > 1there is x > 0
such that Γ(x)> x. The requirement γ > 0ensures that the associated probability distortion
is strictly concave. See Eberlein et al. (2014) for a description of the parameters a, b, c, γ.
2.2. Notation. In addition to the assumptions above, the following notation will be used
throughout the paper.
i. For p[1,], Lp:= Lp(Ω,FT,Q); recall that L1L2... L.
ii. L2(ν) is endowed with the Borel σ-algebra generated by the L2(ν)-norm topology.
iii. For an L2(ν)-valued process {Vt}t0and yRD\{0}, we often write Vt(y) for Vt(ω, y).
iv. Edenotes the Doleans-Dade exponential.
v. Pdenotes the predictable σ-algebra on [0, T ]×Ω.
vi. We often identify the set of test measures Mwith the subset of L1of their Radon
Nikodim derivatives. A weak* topology on Mcan be defined as in Corollary 14.11
of Aliprantis & Border (2006). This topology is equivalent to the weak topology on
L1, i.e. the topology such that if {χn}nN⊂ M, then χnχ∈ M if and only if
Z
C(ω)χn()Z
C(ω)χ(),CL.(2.4)
If M ⊂ L2, we also have the weak topology in L2, i.e. (2.4) must hold for all
CL2. Recall also that, by the Eberlein-Smulian theorem, weak compactness in Lp
is equivalent to weak sequential compactness in Lp, 1 p≤ ∞.
vii. C(Γ) denotes the set of functions qL2(ν) s.t., for A∈ B(RD\{0}) with ν(A)<,
Γ(ν(A)) ZA
q(y)ν(dy)Γ+(ν(A)).(2.5)
viii For Γ+,Γdifferentiable and D= 1, we set
(2.6) ψΓ(y) := Γ
+(ν([y, ))) 11{y>0}Γ
(ν((−∞, y]))) 11{y<0},
ψΓ(y) := Γ
(ν([y, ))) 11{y>0}+ Γ
+(ν((−∞, y]))) 11{y<0}.
ix For Γ+,Γdifferentiable and D= 1, Q(Γ) and Q(Γ) denote test measures under
which the compensator of Nis respectively given by
(1 + ψΓ(y))ν(dy),(1 + ψΓ(y))ν(dy)
摘要:

EXTREMEMEASURESINCONTINUOUSTIMECONICFINANCEYOSHIHIROSHIRAIUniversityofMaryland,CollegePark,DepartmentofMathematicsAbstract.Dynamicspectralriskmeasuresdefineaclaim’svaluationboundsassupremumandinfimumofexpectationsoftheclaim’spayoffoveradominatedsetofmeasures.Themeasuresatwhichsuchextremaareattaineda...

展开>> 收起<<
EXTREME MEASURES IN CONTINUOUS TIME CONIC FINANCE YOSHIHIRO SHIRAI University of Maryland College Park Department of Mathematics.pdf

共30页,预览5页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

声明:本站为文档C2C交易模式,即用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。玖贝云文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知玖贝云文库,我们立即给予删除!

相关推荐

分类:图书资源 价格:10玖币 属性:30 页 大小:1.38MB 格式:PDF 时间:2025-05-06

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 30
客服
关注